Can We Avoid Another Financial Crisis?
eBook - ePub

Can We Avoid Another Financial Crisis?

Steve Keen

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Can We Avoid Another Financial Crisis?

Steve Keen

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

The Great Financial Crash had cataclysmic effects on the global economy, and took conventional economists completely by surprise. Many leading commentators declared shortly before the crisis that the magical recipe for eternal stability had been found. Less than a year later, the biggest economic crisis since the Great Depression erupted. In this explosive book, Steve Keen, one of the very few economists who anticipated the crash, shows why the self-declared experts were wrong and how ever–rising levels of private debt make another financial crisis almost inevitable unless politicians tackle the real dynamics causing financial instability. He also identifies the economies that have become 'The Walking Dead of Debt', and those that are next in line – including Australia, Belgium, China, Canada and South Korea. A major intervention by a fearlessly iconoclastic figure, this book is essential reading for anyone who wants to understand the true nature of the global economic system.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Can We Avoid Another Financial Crisis? an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Can We Avoid Another Financial Crisis? by Steve Keen in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economia & Politica economica. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
Polity
Year
2017
ISBN
9781509513765
Edition
1

1
From Triumph to Crisis in Economics

There was a time when the question this book poses would have generated derisory guffaws from leading economists – and that time was not all that long ago. In December 2003, the Nobel Prize winner Robert Lucas began his Presidential Address to the American Economic Association with the triumphant claim that economic crises like the Great Depression were now impossible:
Macroeconomics was born as a distinct field in the 1940s, as a part of the intellectual response to the Great Depression. The term then referred to the body of knowledge and expertise that we hoped would prevent the recurrence of that economic disaster. My thesis in this lecture is that macroeconomics in this original sense has succeeded: Its central problem of depression prevention has been solved, for all practical purposes, and has in fact been solved for many decades. (Lucas, 2003, p. 1, emphasis added)
Four years later, that claim fell apart, as first the USA and then the global economy entered the deepest and longest crisis since the Great Depression. Almost a decade later, the recovery from that crisis is fragile at best. The question of whether another financial crisis may occur can no longer be glibly dismissed.
That question was first posed decades earlier by the then unknown but now famous maverick American economist Hyman Minsky. Writing two decades before Lucas, Minsky remarked that ‘The most significant economic event of the era since World War II is something that has not happened: there has not been a deep and long-lasting depression’ (1982, p. ix).1 In contrast, before the Second World War, ‘serious recessions happened regularly . . . to go more than thirty-five years without a severe and protracted depression is a striking success’. To Minsky, this meant that the most important questions in economics were:
Can ‘It’ – a Great Depression – happen again? And if ‘It’ can happen, why didn’t ‘It’ occur in the years since World War II? These are questions that naturally follow from both the historical record and the comparative success of the past thirty-five years. (1982, p. xii)
Minsky’s ultimate conclusion was that crises in pure free-market capitalism were inevitable, because thanks to its financial system, capitalism ‘is inherently flawed, being prone to booms, crises, and depressions:
This instability, in my view, is due to characteristics the financial system must possess if it is to be consistent with full-blown capitalism. Such a financial system will be capable of both generating signals that induce an accelerating desire to invest and of financing that accelerating investment. (Minsky, 1969, p. 224)
A serious crisis hadn’t occurred since the Second World War, Minsky argued, because the post-war economy was not a pure free-market system, but rather was a mixed market–state economy where the state was five times larger than it was before the Great Depression. A crisis had been prevented because spending by ‘Big Government’ during recessions had prevented ‘the collapse of profits which is a necessary condition for a deep and long depression’ (Minsky, 1982, p. xiii).
Given that Minsky reached this conclusion in 1982, and that Lucas’s claim that the problem ‘of depression prevention has been solved . . . for many decades’ occurred in 2003, you might think that Lucas, like Minsky, thought that ‘Big Government’ prevented depressions, and that this belief was proven false by the 2008 crisis.
If only it were that simple. In fact, Lucas had reached precisely the opposite opinions about the stability of capitalism and the desirable policy to Minsky, because the question that preoccupied him was not Minsky’s ‘Can “It” – a Great Depression – happen again?’, but the rather more esoteric question ‘Can we derive macroeconomic theory from microeconomics?’
Ever since Keynes wrote The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936), economists have divided their discipline into two components: ‘microeconomics’, which considers the behaviour of consumers and firms; and ‘macroeconomics’, which considers the behaviour of the economy as a whole. Microeconomics has always been based on a model of consumers who aimed to maximise their utility, firms that aimed to maximise their profits, and a market system that achieved equilibrium between these two forces by equating supply and demand in every market. Macroeconomics before Lucas, on the other hand, was based on a mathematical interpreta-tion of Keynes’s attempt to explain why the Great Depression occurred, which was developed not by Keynes but by his contemporary John Hicks.
Though Hicks himself regarded his IS-LM model (‘Investment-Savings & Liquidity-Money’) as compatible with microeconomic theory (Hicks, 1981, p. 153; 1937, pp. 141–2), Lucas did not, because the model implied that government spending could boost aggregate demand during recessions. This was inconsistent with standard microeconomics, which argued that markets work best in the absence of government interventions.
Starting in the late 1960s, Lucas and his colleagues developed an approach to macroeconomics which was derived directly from standard microeconomic theory, which they called ‘New Classical Macroeconomics’. In contrast to the IS-LM model, it asserted that, if consumers and firms were rational – which Lucas and his disciples interpreted to mean (a) that consumers and firms modelled the future impact of government policies using the economic theory that Lucas and his colleagues had developed, and (b) that this theory accurately predicted the consequences of those policies – then the government would be unable to alter aggregate demand because, whatever it did, the public would do the opposite:
there is no sense in which the authority has the option to conduct countercyclical policy . . . by virtue of the assumption that expectations are rational, there is no feedback rule that the authority can employ and expect to be able systematically to fool the public. (Sargent & Wallace, 1976, pp. 177–8)
Over the next few decades, this vision of a microfounded macroeconomics in which the government was largely impotent led to the development of complicated mathematical models of the economy, which became known as ‘Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium’ (DSGE) models.
This intellectual process was neither peaceful nor apolitical. The first models, known as ‘Real Business Cycle’ (RBC) models, assumed that all markets worked perfectly, and asserted that all unemployment was voluntary – including the 25 per cent unemployment rates of the Great Depression (Prescott, 1999; Cole & Ohanian, 2004). This was too much for many economists, and what is now known as the ‘Freshwater–Saltwater’ divide developed within the mainstream of the profession.
The more politically progressive ‘Saltwater’ economists (who described themselves as ‘New Keynesians’) took the RBC models developed by their ‘Freshwater’ rivals and added in ‘market imperfections’ – which were also derived from standard microeconomic theory – to generate DSGE models. The market imperfections built into these models meant that if the model economy were disturbed from equilibrium by a ‘shock’, ‘frictions’ due to those imperfections would slow down the return to equilibrium, resulting in both slower growth and involuntary unemployment.
These ‘New Keynesian’ DSGE models came to dominate macroeconomic theory and policy around the world, and by 2007 they were the workhorse models of Treasuries and Central Banks. A representative (and, at the time, very highly regarded) DSGE model of the US economy had two types of firms (final goods producers operating in a ‘perfect’ market, and intermediate goods producers operating in an ‘imperfect’ one); one type of household (a worker–capitalist–bond trader amalgam that supplied labour via a trade union, earnt dividends from the two types of firms, and received interest income from government bonds); a trade union setting wages; and a government sector consisting of a revenue-constrained, bond-issuing fiscal authority and an activist Central Bank, which varied the interest rate in response to deviations of inflation and GDP growth from its target (Smets & Wouters, 2007).
Notably, a government that could affect employment by fiscal policy was normally absent from DSGE models, as was a financial sector – and indeed money itself. The mindset that developed within the economics profession – and especially within Central Banks – was that these factors could be ignored in macroeconomics. Instead, if the Central Bank used DSGE models to guide policy, and therefore set the interest rate properly, economic growth and inflation would both reach desirable levels, and the economy would reach a Nirvana state of full employment and low inflation.
Right up until mid-2007, this model of the economy seemed to accurately describe the real world. Unemployment, which had peaked at 11 per cent in the USA in the 1983 recession, peaked at under 8 per cent in the early 1990s recession and just over 6 per cent in the early 2000s recession: the clear trend was for lower unemployment over time. Inflation, which had peaked at almost 15 per cent in 1980, peaked at just over 6 per cent in 1991 and under 4 per cent in the early 2000s: it was also heading down. New Keynesian economists believed that these developments showed that their management of the economy was working, and this vindicated their approach to economic modelling. They coined the term ‘The Great Moderation’ (Stock & Watson, 2002) to describe this period of falling peaks in unemployment and inflation, and attributed its occurrence to their management of the economy. Ex-Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke was particularly vocal in congratulating economists for this phenomenon:
Recessions have become less frequent and milder, and quarter-to-quarter volatility in output and employment has declined significantly as well. The sources of the Great Moderation remain somewhat controversial, but as I have argued elsewhere, there is evidence for the view that improved control of inflation has contributed in important measure to this welcome change in the economy. (Bernanke, 2004, emphasis added)
Using DSGE models, official economics bodies like the OECD forecast that 2008 was going to be a bumper year. As 2007 commenced, unemployment in the USA was at the boom level of 4.5 per cent, inflation was right on the Federal Reserve’s 2 per cent target, and according to the OECD in June of 2007, the future – for both the USA and the global economy – was bright:
In its Economic Outlook last Autumn, the OECD took the view that the US slowdown was not heralding a period of worldwide economic weakness, unlike, for instance, in 2001. Rather, a ‘smooth’ rebalancing was to be expected, with Europe taking over the baton from the United States in driving OECD growth.
Recent developments have broadly confirmed this prognosis. Indeed, the current economic situation is in many ways better than what we have experienced in years. Against that background, we have stuck to the rebalancing scenario. Our central forecast remains indeed quite benign: a soft landing in the United States, a strong and sustained recovery in Europe, a solid trajectory in Japan and buoyant activity in China and India. In line with recent trends, sustained growth in OECD economies would be underpinned by strong job creation and falling unemployment. (Cotis, 2007, emphasis added)
This rosy forecast was wrong even before it was published. US unemployment bottomed at 4.4 per cent in March 2007, and by December 2007 it had hit 5 per cent. By this stage, financial markets were in turmoil, but guided by their DSGE models, mainstream economists thought the increase in unemployment was not a major concern. In December 2007, David Stockton, Director of the Division of Research and Statistics at the Federal Reserve, assured its interest-rate-setting authority the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) that there would be no recession in 2008:
Overall, our forecast could admittedly be read as still painting a pretty benign picture: despite all the financial turmoil, the economy avoids recession and, even with steeply higher prices for food and energy and a lower exchange value of the dollar, we achieve some modest edging-off of inflation. (FOMC, 2007)
In stark contrast to the predictions of the Federal Reserve’s models, unemployment rose more rapidly in 2008 and 2009 than at any time since the Great Depression. Inflation briefly spiked to 5 per cent in mid-2008, but then did something it had not done since the end of the Korean War: it turned negative, hitting minus 2 per cent in mid-2009. The financial markets threw up crisis after crisis, and could no longer be ignored by mainstream economists, despite the absence of the financial sector from their models.
Clearly, something was badly amiss. The confidence with which Lucas had dismissed the possibility of a Great Depression a mere four years earlier evaporated, and the response of economists in authority was sheer panic. Temporarily, they threw their economic models out the window, and pumped government money into the economy: they weren’t about to let capitalism collapse on their watch. As then Treasury Secretary Hank Paulson put it in his memoir On the Brink, by late 2008, officials in the US administration had come to believe th...

Table of contents