Institutions and Agrarian Development
eBook - ePub

Institutions and Agrarian Development

A New Approach to West Africa

Erwin Bulte, Paul Richards, Maarten Voors

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Institutions and Agrarian Development

A New Approach to West Africa

Erwin Bulte, Paul Richards, Maarten Voors

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book argues that development strategies have thus far failed in Western Africa because the many challenges afflicting the area have yet to be explored and understood from the perspective of institutional resources. With a particular focus on three countries on the bend of the Upper West African coast – Guinea, Liberia and Sierra Leone – this book offers a theory to account for the nature of these institutional elements, to test deductions against evidence, and finally to propose a reset for rural development policy to make fuller use of local institutional resources. Based on quantitative analysis and eight years of multidisciplinary field research, this volume features several large-scale RCTs in the domain of rural development, local governance, and nature conservation. The authors address one of the biggest topics in agricultural and development economics today: the structural transformation of poor, agrarian economies, and they do so through the important and unique lens ofinstitutions.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Institutions and Agrarian Development an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Institutions and Agrarian Development by Erwin Bulte, Paul Richards, Maarten Voors in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Betriebswirtschaft & Agribusiness. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2018
ISBN
9783319985008
© The Author(s) 2018
Erwin Bulte, Paul Richards and Maarten VoorsInstitutions and Agrarian DevelopmentPalgrave Studies in Agricultural Economics and Food Policyhttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-98500-8_1
Begin Abstract

1. Introduction

Erwin Bulte1 , Paul Richards2 and Maarten Voors1
(1)
Development Economics Group, Wageningen University and Research, Wageningen, The Netherlands
(2)
Directorate of Research and Planning, Njala University, Mokonde, Sierra Leone
Erwin Bulte (Corresponding author)
Paul Richards
Maarten Voors
End Abstract
Many formerly poor countries have seen remarkable economic and social progress in recent decades. Large parts of Asia and South and Central America—India, China, Brazil, to mention only the most obvious instances—have achieved unprecedented levels of material prosperity in recent times, even though inequality remains a deeply ingrained problem.
Africa presents a different picture. Many African countries have reached rather impressive economic growth rates since the mid-1990s. However, the gains have been unequally divided and have been diluted by population growth. Scattered islands of economic improvement are set in an “ocean” of countries mired in extreme poverty and social dislocation.
Thirty-eight African countries are among the bottom 25 per cent of the countries in the United Nations human development index for 2016 (a measure assessing human emancipation and security alongside material prosperity).
Persistent poverty correlates with high rates of population growth. African economic weakness means that not enough jobs are created for a burgeoning younger generation.
Despairing of their future if they stay at home, many young people, especially young men, set their sights on emigration , especially to European countries to the north. A considerable number are prepared to risk putting themselves into the hands of smugglers, who run what is, in effect, a modern slave trade across the Mediterranean.
And yet, Africa has abundant (agrarian) resources. Many of the trans-Mediterranean migrants come from West Africa. Why is this belt of relatively lightly populated and well-watered land on the margins of the tropical rain forest not playing the same role as the agrarian frontier of nineteenth-century North America as a generator of jobs and prosperity?
A number of explanations have been advanced to explain the failure of West African agriculture to catalyse far-reaching economic change.
Some stress geographic and environmental constraints, such as poor soil or diseases such as malaria and sleeping sickness. Others point to human factors, such as the consequences of several centuries or more of the transatlantic and trans-Saharan slave trades, or the exploitation of small-scale farmers under “extractive ” colonial and postcolonial economic regimes. Yet others point their fingers at “backward technology” (a lack of machines or high-yielding seeds).
These arguments, though hotly contested, are not necessarily wrong.
In this book, however, we pay attention to a different dimension of the African agrarian puzzle—namely, institutional factors. Institutional constraints, we argue, permeate, and shape these other constraints. They have a logic and dynamic of their own. Institutions are important. They require to be addressed in their own right. Any fuller understanding of the potential for African agrarian change requires sustained attention to the institutional dynamics of agrarian society and economy.
What are institutions? We engage with this question more thoroughly in the main body of the book. But to start with, a couple of instances might be helpful here.
Soccer—now a universal game—originated as a medieval form of street ritual in which two crowds drove a pig’s bladder towards opposing goals. The ritual evolved into a field sport played in a number of British schools in the first half of the nineteenth century. The modern game emerged in the mid-nineteenth century, when players who had learnt to play under variant rules met at university and wanted to continue to play. They founded the Football Association to administer a single set of written rules. The point we wish to emphasize is that the institution of soccer long predated the formal rules under which it now operates. The existence of an institution is not to be judged by whether or not it has a set of formal rules.
A second instructive example is provided by the rule of the road. Archaeologists working on a Roman quarry site in Wiltshire established from the relative depth of track grooves made by empty and laden carts leaving the site that Roman vehicles kept to the left when passing (Walters 1998). Keeping to the left seems to have been the preferred order for armed riders passing on horseback from ancient times. Right-handed riders would want their sword arm on the passing side, and about 85 per cent of the population is right handed. A change towards driving/riding on the right spread across Europe in the wake of the conquests of Napoleon Bonaparte. Today, driving on the right is the norm in a majority of countries sharing land borders. The older custom of driving on the left survived mainly in island countries, such as Japan, the United Kingdom, and Australia. Expense is often given as the reason for not agreeing on a single universal standard.
These examples illustrate two key points about institutions.
The first is that many institutions emerge as customs (the consolidation of effective practices), rather than through rational planning.
The second is that customary norms can be codified or standardized, but sometimes, reforms are less logical than reformers think. There is no practical or logical reason to prefer to drive on the right or left. The only necessity is to have an agreed rule. It is sometimes claimed that Napoleon changed the rule of the road in continental Europe because he thought it more auspicious to drive on the right. If true, this would be an instance of institutional reform designed to accommodate a superstition.
That so many institutions are so often shaped and modified through the accumulation of inherited practices helps explain the fact that it is often hard to give plausible or convincing explanations of their origins. These origins may be lost in time. “Just so” stories are then invented, to explain an institution, or to protect it from its critics. This makes it challenging to find an objective standpoint to judge an institution as “good” or “bad.” This is a problem because reformers, comfortable with their own institutions, are tempted then to claim that “injustice” or “poverty”—or some other problematic condition—are the result of not sharing the would-be reformer’s institutional values.
Some of these problems of perspective, and how they might be tackled, are addressed in the following chapters, especially Chap. 2, where we outline some of the ways in which economists, anthropologists, and other social scientists undertake institutional analysis.
At this point, however, we need to note a fundamental difference of emphasis that runs through work on institutions in all disciplines. This is between accounts that focus on successional issues (how institutions develop and evolve) and those that focus on integrational issues (how coexisting institutions combine or clash).
The distinguished Nobel laureate in economics Douglass North mainly took the first approach. Over the sweep of economic history, institutions change from limited to open access. In the first instance, a powerful ruler would mediate cases only among a noble elite. Common people could not access the court of the king. Today—and in theory, at least—modern countries offer justice to all.
North also noted that the earliest institutions were informal (based around custom, taboo, or myth), but were later formalized (based around written constitutions and laws). Open access institutions and formalization reduce the transaction costs associated with many areas of social and economic life, whether we are talking about debt recovery or online no fault divorce.
This kind of approach has supported a debate about development and poverty alleviation in which the primary concern is to modernize institutions—sometimes taken as being practically synonymous with the acceptance of key practices and organizational arrangements of advanced market economies. It is for the want of these features that poverty becomes ingrained (or so the argument runs). “Why aren’t you more like Sweden?” is the cry of institutional modernizers.
So, for example, development agencies talk about the need to reform land tenure in an impoverished region such as West Africa, in order for land to become a tradable asset, guaranteed (so it is supposed) to find the best use in the hands of the highest bidder.
Among those who have advanced the integrational approach, we find another Nobel laureate, the economist Oliver Williamson, and a major anthropologist, Mary Douglas. Their work will be discussed in more detail in Chap. 2. A key insight we will reiterate is that the way i...

Table of contents