Hayek: A Collaborative Biography
eBook - ePub

Hayek: A Collaborative Biography

Part III, Fraud, Fascism and Free Market Religion

R. Leeson, R. Leeson

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Hayek: A Collaborative Biography

Part III, Fraud, Fascism and Free Market Religion

R. Leeson, R. Leeson

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

F.A. Hayek (1899-1992), the co-leader of the Austrian free market school, embraced the transparently fraudulent assertion made by Donald McCormick, aka Richard Deacon, in The British Connection which accused A.C. Pigou, the co-leader of the Cambridge market failure school, of being a Soviet spy.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Hayek: A Collaborative Biography an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Hayek: A Collaborative Biography by R. Leeson, R. Leeson in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Economic History. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2015
ISBN
9781137452429
Part I
Fraud
1
Introduction
Robert Leeson
‘Knowledge’, ‘Intelligence’ and fraud
Most ‘Knowledge’, from science through security-related ‘Intelligence’ to religion, is initially community-specific. Different communities have different methods of assessing, accepting and rejecting it; scientific ‘Knowledge’ is generally capable of being replicated, whereas religious knowledge tends to be based on revelation, the Word of scripture or the Voice of authority.
‘Intelligence’ is often surreptitiously derived from Voices that allegedly must – for reasons of national security – be protected from scrutiny.1 ‘Intelligence’ is often acquired (or fabricated) and sold by double and triple agents – and by journalists, fraudsters and agenda-driven politicians. When ex post the privileged status of this ex ante ‘Intelligence’ is stripped away, a different picture can emerge: the USS Maine was probably not blown up by the Spanish (1898); the North Vietnamese probably didn’t attack American ships in the Gulf of Tonkin (1964); the yellow-cake-fuelled smoking-gun mushroom cloud justification of the US invasion of Iraq was not a ‘slam dunk’ (2003) etc.2
The truth content of ‘Intelligence’ assertions are, of course, unrelated to the confidence with which they are uttered. US Secretary of Defence Donald Rumsfeld, for example, stated in 2001 that ‘the great principles of the University of Chicago economics’ would produce the capture of Osama Bin Laden (Leeson 2003, 92); but it was special forces of the United States government – not market forces – which accomplished that task.
When governments send citizens to war, those with the capacity to critically evaluate alleged ‘Intelligence’ – public servants, journalists and academics – are often overwhelmed and partially silenced by patriotic momentum. Indeed, the incentives faced by journalists – at least prior to war-weariness – can become aligned with those who promote war: the Fourth Estate as a ‘traitor’-exposing, domestic fifth column. In The Political Economy of War, A. C. Pigou (1921, 111–112) described the market failure relating to ‘the private interests of makers of armaments’ who ‘promote war scares’ and who were ‘not without influence in the press and through the press on public opinion’.
In the 20th century, three world wars facilitated a Communist revolution, a Fascist backlash and the subsequent collapse of both. The weakness of bureaucratic information flows (relative to market-based competitors) undermined Communist economies – a point emphasized by Frederick Hayek, the co-leader (with Murray Rothbard) of the fourth generation Austrian School of Economics. Flows of information and disinformation played pivotal roles in the First, Second and Third (that is, Cold) World Wars.
The First World War was a religion-endorsed clash of empires with little ideological content; the Second initially pitted Fascists and Communists against democracies (until the Communists were obliged to change sides); the rhetoric of the Cold War was unambiguously ideological.
The two ideological fraternities that rally behind the slogans of liberty and equality have tended to embrace either markets or governments, and to demonize the other fraternity and its preferred social organizer. The advance of democracy and its legitimizing underpinning, tax-subsidized human capital formation, has, however, tended to embrace governments and markets as collaborating social organizers (with a case-by-case comparative evaluation of each). But the market-failure paradigm is not anti-market; market-based solutions (tax- and subsidy-adjusted prices) are available to correct for sub-optimal outcomes.
Nuanced scholarship differs from agitprop. In What Is to Be Done? Burning Questions of Our Movement, Lenin (1961 [1902]) argued that the Equality revolution could not wait; the Marxist ‘vanguard’ must hasten history. In What Is To Be Done?, Rothbard’s (2009 [1961]) confidential memorandum to the tax-exempt William Volker Charities Fund, a similar strategy was outlined for Austrian liberty.3
The dictatorship of the proletariat was the logical extension of Lenin’s agitprop; Fascism was more than the logical extension of liberty – it was embraced by Ludwig von Mises (1985 [1927], 42–51), the co-leader of the third generation Austrian School, who left an eternal instruction to his disciples:
It cannot be denied that Fascism and similar movements aiming at the establishment of dictatorships are full of the best intentions and that their intervention has, for the moment, saved European civilization. The merit that Fascism has thereby won for itself will live on eternally in history.
The ‘similar movements’ of ‘bloody counteraction’ that Mises referred to included the French anti-Semitic Action Française plus ‘Germans and Italians’. ‘Italians’ obviously refers to Mussolini’s 1922 March on Rome; Mises’ (1985 [1927], 44) reference to ‘Ludendorff and Hitler’ means the 1923 Ludendorff-Hitler-Putsch (or Munich Beer Hall Putsch).
Mises (1985 [1927], 49) predicted that:
The deeds of the Fascists and of other parties corresponding to them were emotional reflex actions evoked by indignation at the deeds of the Bolsheviks and Communists. As soon as the first flush of anger had passed, their policy took a more moderate course and will probably become even more so with the passage of time.
Misesian liberals and Fascists were allies, but differed in tactics:
What distinguished liberal from Fascist tactics is not a difference of opinion regarding the use of armed force to resist armed attackers, but a difference in the fundamental estimation about the role of violence in a struggle for power.
Violence was ‘the highest principle’ and must lead to
civil war. The ultimate victor to emerge will be the faction strongest in number ... The decisive question, therefore always remains: How does one obtain a majority for one’s own party? This however is purely an intellectual matter.
Fascism would have to embrace Mises’ (1985 [1927], 50) liberalism to achieve their common aims; if Fascism ‘wanted really to combat socialism it would oppose it with ideas.’ Mises would provide these ideas: ‘There is however only one idea that can be effectively opposed to socialism, viz, liberalism.’ Mises provided an historicist inevitability justification: ‘Fascism will never succeed as completely as Russian Bolshevism from freeing itself from the power of liberal ideas ... The next episode will be the victory of communism.’
Mises’ political activity was consistent with his ideology: on 1 March 1934, he joined the Austro-Fascist Patriotic Front and their Werk Neues Leben social club (HĂŒlsmann 2007, 677, n149). Mises may also have been a victim of propaganda: his justification for this tactical embrace was that fascists would protect property – the protection of which he saw as the very essence of liberty. Meanwhile, tax-evading fascist kleptocrats were eying Jewish property; in the Anschluss of March 1938, Austria was reunited with Austrian-led Germany, and the Austrian Adolf Eichmann opened the Central Office for Jewish Emigration. The decree on the Declaration of Jewish Assets revealed fascism to be a conveyor belt along which Jews had their property confiscated before being exterminated or driven abroad. As The Last Knight of Liberalism bemoaned: ‘Mises family property had become free booty’ (HĂŒlsmann 2007, 728, 677, n149). The Jewish-born Mises was lucky to escape with his life; he devoted much of the rest of it to describing his opponents as ‘Fascists’.
John Maynard Keynes (1919) had resigned from the British government over the peace treaties that had created the resentful environment in which fascism could emerge and thrive. In the early 1970s, the Austrian School, then in its fourth generation, appeared to be nearing an inglorious personal and community end; after a second bout of prolonged depression (1969–1974), Hayek always carried a razor blade with which to slash his wrist (Cubitt 2006, 89).4 However, Mises’ death in 1973 facilitated his School’s resurrection; alive Mises had been a liability, whereas dead he could be marketed as a saint. Benjamin Rogge (1974) reported that at a Philadelphia Society meeting, David Friedman ‘first made clear to us the true fascist nature of [his father] Milton Friedman’s thinking.’ When Rothbard, Richard Ebeling, Gary North, Sudha Shenoy et al. initiated an Austrian revivalist conference in June 1974, one of the highlights was the baiting of Friedman – in person – with the accusation that his son detected ‘latent fascist tendencies’ in him (Ebeling 1974). Shenoy (2003) recalled that ‘Murray Rothbard made the whole affair fun.’
Subsequently, US presidents and presidential hopefuls embraced the Austrian School of Economics. President Ronald Reagan (1984, 198) wrote:
von Mises ... rekindled the flames of liberty in new generations of thinkers ... we owe an incalculable debt to this dean of the Austrian school of economics for expanding our knowledge and inspiring a new vision of liberty in our age.
In 1991, President George H. W. Bush awarded Hayek the Presidential Medal of Freedom.
The 2012 Republican vice-presidential candidate Senator Paul Ryan is reportedly an Austrian disciple. In Mises and Austrian Economics: a Personal View, three-time presidential candidate, Congressman Ron Paul (2008, 52, 37–38) proclaiming that
Liberty is my first goal ... fascists and socialist voices of oppression will grow louder and more influential ... Mises’ prediction that US type of interventionism will leads to German national socialist type of interventionism is accurate ... We can only hope that we can turn things around before his prediction that it leads to a German-style fascism comes true. The non-liberals who admit to the failure of their brand of interventionism now plot schemes for ‘reindustrialisation’ – a euphemism for fascism (government partnership with business).
Paul (2008, 18, 5) declared: ‘Mises was the greatest economist of all time’; Rothbard and Hans Sennholz were
especially helpful in getting firsthand explanations of how the market functions. They helped me to refine my answers to the continual barrage of statist legislation that dominates the U.S. Congress. Their personal assistance was invaluable to me in my educational and political endeavors.
Paul was also helpful to Miseans: in 1976, he employed North (2010, 245–246) to write a weekly newsletter.
For a quarter of a century after World War II, the social democratic ‘middle way’ appeared to prosper. But in the 1970s, the ideological balance shifted. The regulatory wave had successfully tackled various aspects of market failure,5 but had actually exacerbated underlying problems when applied to the control of prices and wages. From the mid-1970s, the deregulation wave began to successfully tackle some of the welf...

Table of contents