Private Property and State Power
eBook - ePub

Private Property and State Power

Philosophical Justifications, Economic Explanations, and the Role of Government

J. Huffman

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Private Property and State Power

Philosophical Justifications, Economic Explanations, and the Role of Government

J. Huffman

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book details the relationship between private property and government. As private property is important to both individual welfare and the public interest, the book provides an intellectual framework for the analysis and resolution of contemporary property rights disputes.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Private Property and State Power an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Private Property and State Power by J. Huffman in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Law & Civil Law. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2013
ISBN
9781137376725
Topic
Law
Subtopic
Civil Law
Index
Law
CHAPTER 1
INTRODUCTION
Every person on the planet possesses private property, even if it is nothing more than the shirt on one’s back and the food one consumes, and even if the political regime a person is subject to has declared that there is no such thing as private property. Things that can be used or enjoyed by only one or a few people at a given point in time belong, as a practical matter, to those using or enjoying them at that moment.
It might be objected, particularly by lawyers and others experienced in the formalities of the law, that the foregoing assertion is nonsense. The shirt and food could well belong to others, or to no one. The wearer of the shirt and the consumer of the food could have borrowed or stolen them from their rightful owners, or they could have found them abandoned by the roadside. True enough. These are the sorts of questions we have lawyers and judges to sort out, and over the centuries we have developed a labyrinth of property laws to determine whether those who use and enjoy things are the rightful owners.
These are important questions, but they are not the concern of this book or of its companion volume, Private Property and the Constitution: State Powers, Public Rights, and Economic Liberties. Who owns what is the subject of many a property law treatise. The assertion in the opening paragraph, a claim I elaborate on at some length in Chapter 3, is only that private property is inevitable. Simple physics dictates that most things can be used, occupied, enjoyed, or consumed by a finite number of people (often a single person) at any given moment in time. That means there must be social understandings about which person or people will “own” a particular thing at a particular time. This understanding could range from the intricate complexities of modern property law, to custom, to reluctant yielding to brute physical force.
Saying that everything belongs to everybody, or that the state or the community owns some or all things, will not change the simple physics. There must be some system of rules or customary practices for determining who those people will be—whether the de facto owners are the rightful owners.
Of course there are things, like air and water, which can be used or enjoyed simultaneously by literally millions of people, but, as we have learned the hard way, too many people emitting pollutants into the air or boating on the public waters can negatively affect the health or enjoyment of others. So we regulate air pollution and grant permits to commercial and recreational boaters, which is really an official recognition that polluters may pollute within the regulatory limits and that some people, but not others, can boat on the “public” waters.
Although the physics of occupation, use, and enjoyment makes some system of private property necessary even in the case of resources in infinite supply, few if any resources valued by humans are actually limitless. As in the examples of air and water, seemingly abundant resources can be scarce in particular locations, especially densely populated locations. Thus, scarcity amplifies the need for a system of rules establishing which individuals have the right to use particular resources at particular times.
Whether the system of rules is called private property, common property, public property, or whatever label we choose to attach, there is no avoiding that the ultimate question to be answered, pursuant to whatever the controlling rules may be, is who gets to use what resources at a particular point in time. In other words, any system of rules for the use, occupation, and enjoyment of things will define the legal relationships among people with respect to things (including intangible things like stocks, bonds, patents, copyrights, and goodwill).
In the deep recesses of human history, there are no doubt examples of small and isolated communities in which this necessary system of property rules was purely customary. But it is difficult to imagine any community in which there were not occasional disagreements about the rules or their application to particular situations. In those circumstances, there needed to be a person or persons whose interpretation of the property rules was authoritative and determinative of the outcome of the dispute. We could call these interpreters and enforcers of the rules whatever we like, but almost everywhere in the modern world we recognize them as instrumentalities of the state and its many subsidiaries.
Thus, private property and what Robert Nozick called the “minimal state”1 are an inevitable part of any system for the allocation of scarce resources. A few hardcore libertarians might object that we could do without the state by relying on private covenants to establish rules of resource use and systems for dispute resolution, but the reality in the United States and elsewhere is that the state exists as the ultimate authority on property rights and their enforcement.
In every society the laws and customs of private property are influenced by culture and history. But they are also of our own design. Contrary to the nineteenth-century beliefs of thinkers like Karl Marx in politics, Auguste Comte in sociology, and Herbert Spencer in economics, human history is not linear. As legal scholar Grant Gilmore observed several decades ago,2 legal systems and other social institutions reflect human choice, not destiny or something resembling Darwinian, biological evolution. While the natural rights tradition in American constitutional law invites the claim that private property is a gift from God, the reality is that the rules and institutions we rely upon in allocating property rights are significantly of our own choosing.
If we are to choose well, meaning if we are to choose laws and institutions that promote our societal ambitions, we must understand what the alternatives are and how they work. We must understand how different property systems affect relationships among people with respect to scarce resources. How do people respond to the incentives presented by different rules for use, occupation, or consumption of those resources? What are the consequences of alternative roles for the state in the administration of property rules and in the direct control of resource use? The rules and institutions we embrace will significantly affect human welfare and freedom, as well as the environment and resources base on which future generations will depend.
This book and its companion volume examine the integral relationship between private property and the state. In recounting property rights disputes in Hawaii, Connecticut, and Oregon, Chapter 2 demonstrates the tension between the state’s role as definer and enforcer of property rights and the threats state power poses for property rights. Chapter 3 provides a layman’s explanation of property and the various forms of property that exist in the United States and other common law countries. Chapter 4 summarizes a wide range of philosophical justifications for (and critiques of) private property and Chapter 5 examines economic theories that seek to explain the real-world consequences of reliance on a system of private property. Chapter 6 discusses the role of the state, with an emphasis on the tension inherent in being definer and enforcer of property rights on the one hand and regulator of property rights on the other.
The second volume, Private Property and the Constitution: State Powers, Public Rights, and Economic Liberties, examines the constitutional protections designed to limit the negative effects of state regulations of private property and thus minimize the tension between the state’s two essential functions.
CHAPTER 2
PROPERTY AND GOVERNMENT: AN UNAVOIDABLE TENSION
Private property is both dependent on and threatened by government. Government establishes and enforces the rules of property ownership and use, defines the scope and content of property rights, and through its courts resolves disputes over those rights. At the same time, government regulations place limits on private property and sometimes have the effect of destroying much of its value. It is an unavoidable tension.
There are those who contend that property systems can exist entirely by private agreement—that government is unnecessary, even an obstacle, to an effective private property regime. But private agreements are contracts and contract depends on government. Government establishes and enforces the rules of contract. Of course, those who argue that government is unnecessary to property generally take the same view of contract.
To be sure, there is much in life, even modern, globalized life, that depends only on trust and a handshake. But human nature assures that more is usually needed. A few folks can’t be trusted. Even those who can be trusted will sometimes disagree about what they agreed to. Trustworthy, well-intentioned people cannot anticipate every eventuality. They cannot provide by contract for every contingency and for every possible conflict that may later arise regarding the boundary between one property right and another. It is true they can contract a third party to resolve such future disagreements, but centuries of experience demonstrate, even in small communities, that the third party will quickly become some form of what we think of as government. Certainly, private contract and property regimes have existed, and it is interesting to speculate about how they might work on a more expansive scale, but the reality in the United States is that our system of private property is heavily dependent on government.
At the same time, the greatest threat to property is government. All of the nation’s thieves and mafia dons combined pose less of a threat to private property than your average county government. This is not because county governments are filled with talented crooks more ruthless than the mafia. To the contrary, most government officials are sincere and devoted public servants intent on providing for the health, safety, and welfare of the public. But they have enormous powers at their fingertips. In addition to defining and enforcing property rights, they can tax, regulate, and take property by eminent domain. Separately or together, these powers are sufficient to destroy private property rights unless constrained in some way. In the American system of government the constraints are only two: the will of the majority and the constitutions of the state and federal governments.
Thus there is an unavoidable tension between property and government. Property depends on government, yet much of what government does can have serious impacts on the value, security, and privacy of property. Three stories will illustrate the tension.
THREE TALES IN WHICH PRIVATE PROPERTY AND GOVERNMENT COLLIDE
A Problem in Paradise
In the 1960s, the Hawaii Legislature decided that all was not perfect in the newest American state. Although many Hawaiians owned their homes, few of them owned the underlying land. Half of the land in the state was owned by the Federal and State governments. Most of the remainder was owned by 72 landowners. On the island of Oahu, where most of Hawaii’s population resides, 22 landowners held nearly three quarters of the private lands. This concentration of private lands in very few owners was the product of a feudal-like system dating back to the settlement of the Hawaiian Islands by seafaring Polynesians from the western Pacific Ocean. For each island there was a royal high chief, the ali i nui, who controlled all the land and assigned subchiefs to arrange for the use of those lands. Individuals occupied and farmed the land with the approval and at the discretion of the subchiefs. There was no private property in land, at least not for ordinary people.
By whatever theory royalty originally controlled Hawaii’s lands, there was no doubt that their 72 successors held clear title to the land when Hawaii became a state in 1959. The new Hawaiian legislators took the view that this concentration of land ownership adversely affected the economy of the State and the health, welfare, security, and happiness of the people of the State. Worse yet, said the legislators, “[i]f the inflationary trend of land continues unchecked, the resultant inflationary total cost of living could create such a large population of persons deprived of decent and healthful standards of life that the consequent disruptions in lawful social behavior could irreparably rend the social fabric which now protectively covers the life and safety of all Hawaii’s people.”1
In the face of these perceived threats to the state and its people, the Hawaii Legislature enacted The Land Reform Act of 1967.2 Under the Act, tenants living in single family homes in housing tracts of at least five acres could petition the Hawaii Housing Authority to condemn the land on which their houses sit. After a hearing to determine that condemnation of the leased land would serve the public purposes of the Land Reform Act, the Housing Authority could acquire all or some of the lots at prices determined in a condemnation trial or agreed to between the lessees and lessors. The lots would then be sold to interested tenants, leased back to tenants not wishing to purchase, or sold to other individuals. No individual could purchase more than one lot and the Housing Authority was not permitted to make a profit on the sale. As a practical matter, the money used to compensate the large landowners came from the tenants who chose to purchase their lots. The state collected the payments from the purchasers and passed it on to those whose lands had been condemned.
This was not land reform in the style of uncompensated expropriations that have occurred in many countries of the world. The large landowners of Hawaii were paid for their lands. Nevertheless, they were forced to sell and thus unhappy with the Land Reform Act and the powers it gave the state to condemn their land. One of the largest landowners in the state was the Bishop Estate that controlled all of the lands that had once belonged to Princess Bernice Pauahi Bishop, the great-granddaughter and last lineal descendant of Kamehameha the Great, the first monarch of Hawaii.
Princess Bernice’s will established a perpetual charitable trust for the establishment and support of the Kamehameha Schools for the education of children of native Hawaiian ancestry. The trustees of the Bishop Estate filed suit in federal district court. Their case, Hawaii Housing Authority v. Midkiff,3 challenged the state’s authority to condemn the property of one private owner and transfer it to another. The estate claimed, among other things, that the Hawaii Land Reform Act violated the US Constitution’s 14th Amendment due process clause that had nearly a century earlier been held to require state compliance with the 5th Amendment’s clause prohibiting the taking of private property except for a public use and only with just compensation.4 The District Court ruled against Princess Bernice’s estate, who appealed to the 9th Circuit Court of Appeals.5 The appellate court reversed the lower court, calling the Hawaii law “a naked attempt on the part of the state of Hawaii to take the private property of A and transfer it to B solely for B’s private use and benefit.”6 This, the court said, was precisely what the public use clause was meant to prevent.
The US Supreme Court then granted Hawaii’s petition for review. In addition to the filings of the two parties to the case, five friend of the court (amicus) briefs were filed. Not surprisingly, 28 states joined on a single brief in support of the position of the State of Hawaii. Three briefs were filed in support of the ...

Table of contents