Behavioral Economics
eBook - ePub

Behavioral Economics

Moving Forward

Fabrizio Ghisellini, Beryl Y. Chang

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Behavioral Economics

Moving Forward

Fabrizio Ghisellini, Beryl Y. Chang

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

This book sets the agenda to turn behavioral economics, which has long been considered a subordinate discipline, into mainstream economics. Ghisellini and Chang expose the conceptual and empirical inadequacy of conventional economics using illustrations of real world decision-making in a dynamic environment, including evidence from the global financial crisis. With a rigorous yet accessible style, they give a comprehensive overview of behavioral economics and of the current state of play in the field across different schools of thought. Seven major conceptual problems still affecting the development of behavioral economics are identified and the authors propose research avenues to address these issues and allow the discipline to receive its long-awaited recognition.

Crucial reading for researchers and students looking for insights into the many unsolved problems of economics.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on ā€œCancel Subscriptionā€ - itā€™s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time youā€™ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlegoā€™s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan youā€™ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, weā€™ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Behavioral Economics an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Behavioral Economics by Fabrizio Ghisellini, Beryl Y. Chang in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Economics & Economic Theory. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2018
ISBN
9783319752051
Part IHow did we get here?
Ā© The Author(s) 2018
Fabrizio Ghisellini and Beryl Y. ChangBehavioral Economicshttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-75205-1_1
Begin Abstract

1. Introduction to Part I

Fabrizio Ghisellini1 and Beryl Y. Chang2
(1)
Center for Monetary and Financial Studies LUISS University, Rome, Italy
(2)
New York University, New York, NY, USA
End Abstract
How to begin?
Before we plunge into the ā€œunfinished businessesā€ in behavioral economics, it is appropriate to give a refreshing overview of ā€œhow we got hereā€, that is, the process by which behavioral economics has become a serious competitor to what we call ā€œconventional economicsā€ (CE). And this is what we deal with in Part I.
To start with, Chap. 2 gives a concise but complete report on the rise and fall of conventional economics . We identify contemporary conventional economics with New Classical Economics, led by people such as Nobel laureate Robert J. Lucas and Thomas Sargent, which has been mainstream throughout the last three decades of the last century and beyond. In this section, we present:
  • the conceptual pillars of decision-making in conventional economics (i.e. expected discounted utility , rational choice, and rational expectations )
  • an example of the decision-making process for the leading character of conventional economics , the homo economicus , who has wealth maximization as the sole target, is characterized by consistent preferences and linear time discounting, acts in splendid isolation, and is endowed with complete information and advanced computing capabilities. In particular, after introducing the efficient market hypothesis (EMH), we show the way in which the homo economicus would be supposed to elaborate and implement an asset allocation strategy
  • analytical evidence of the inadequacy of conventional economics , including EMH, to fit reality, using as a litmus test what happened during the global financial crisis begun in 2007
Chapter 3 is devoted to an overview of the behavioral economics revolution.
We first present the reasons for the emergence and the success of behavioral economics. We then proceed to highlight the features of the behavioral ā€œversionsā€ of utility and rationality . Utility is no longer just egotistic wealth maximization, but a much wider and complex concept which can also be a function of drivers related to fairness and altruism.
Similarly, behavioral economics questions the conventional view of rationality (based on consistency and coherence ). So to start with, we review the seminal contribution of Nobel Prize winner Herbert Simon, who 60 years ago introduced the concepts of bounded rationality and ā€œsatisficingā€ choices. Then, after giving an account of the major breakthrough implied by the prospect theory developed by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, we compare the different tenets of the ā€œAmericanā€ and the ā€œGermanā€ schools: for the former, people who use heuristics (mental shortcuts) are plagued by biases and therefore make irrational choices; for the latter, which has its most influential advocate in Gerd Gigerenzer, heuristics are in fact ā€œecologically rationalā€, that is, optimal if environmental factors are taken into account in the decision-making. After describing the way in which real-world people take decisions, we investigate the extent to which the psychological insights introduced by behavioral economics fit reality, using again the global financial crisis as a test bed.
So with Part I of the book, a (hopefully) complete and clear account of how we got here is given.
Ā© The Author(s) 2018
Fabrizio Ghisellini and Beryl Y. ChangBehavioral Economicshttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-75205-1_2
Begin Abstract

2. Does Conventional Economics Fit Reality?

Fabrizio Ghisellini1 and Beryl Y. Chang2
(1)
Center for Monetary and Financial Studies LUISS University, Rome, Italy
(2)
New York University, New York, NY, USA
End Abstract

2.1 The Rise of New Classical Economics

As it is often the case in history, what is now considered conventional started off as a revolution. Economics is no exception. The revolution began in the early 1970s, especially in the work of Robert Lucas (Nobel Prize winner in 1995) at the University of Chicago, and its name was New Classical Economics.
Given that this book is mainly about behavioral economics and decision-making, in what follows we only give a brief account of the main innovations and tenets of the New Classical paradigm as regards macroeconomics, and focus instead on its basic microeconomic pillars (e.g. utility and rationality).
The name ā€œNew Classicalā€ was meant to suggest a revival of the Classical Economics, against the then prevailing Keynesian school of thought. In Keynesā€™ view, the macroeconomic framework was especially prone to the possible shortage of aggregate demand (the sum of consumption, investment, government expenditure, and net exports), and recessions would in that case readily ensue. In particular, the sequence of events could begin with a fall in private investments. With firms producing less and, given wage stickiness, unable in the short term to cut wages to a level which would be in any case acceptable for workers, the net result is the appearance of ā€œinvoluntary unemploymentā€. In such a situation, an increase in public expenditure is key to boost aggregate demand and bring the system back to equilibrium.
This account of reality seemed quite inconceivable to Lucas and his fellow New Classicals (including famous economists such as Thomas Sargent, Robert J. Barro, and Edward Prescott), as for them price changes would ensure that markets always tend to equilibrium and agents always optimize. If for whatever occasional reasons private investments fell, firms would promptly cut wages to restore profits and workers would accept the best option available (i.e. lower wages) rather than facing unemployment. So, very much as it was the case for the ā€œoldā€ Classicals, equilibrium is almost always there.
Almost always. Fluctuations in output can indeed occur, and they can be large and/or persistent. In the latter case, the explanation given by New Classicals is structural, as it has to do with productivity/technology changes, which require the entire system to adapt, and of course that may take some time. What is perhaps even more interesting is, however, the interpretation given to non-structural shocks.
As a matter of fact, in order for the New Classicalsā€™ macroeconomic policies (fiscal and monetary policies) to have any effects on real output, they are subject to one conditionā€”they must be unanticipated by economic agents. Why? In order to give a satisfactory answer to this question, we should take a step back to what was one of the most successful concepts until the New Classicals showed up on the macroeconomic scene: the Phillips curve.
In 1958, A. W. H. Phillips published in the Economica magazine the results of his study of wage inflation and unemployment in the United Kingdom from 1861 to 1957, which highlighted an inverse relationship between the two variables, as visualized in Fig. 2.1.
../images/454770_1_En_2_Chapter/454770_1_En_2_Fig1_HTML.png
Fig. 2.1
Basic Phillips Curve
During the 1960s, this led many to believe that, through the use of monetary policy, governments could choose the combination of inflation and unemployment which was deemed more suitable in any specific circumstance. Unfortunately, that turned out to be not the case. In the US, during the 1970s, the average inflation rate rose by about 4.5% vis-Ć -vis the previous decade, and the response of the unemployment rate was not a reduction, but an increase of more than 2%.
From a theoretical point of view, the first (big) nail on the coffin of the simplest version of the Phillips curve was placed by important economists like Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps. They stressed that the key adjustment variable for equating labor demand and supply is the real wage, rather than the nominal one. Given that there is just one equilibrium real wage, there is also only one long-run unemployment rate, the natural rate of unemployment. While in the short run monetary policy may produce real effects while people recalculate the level of real wages, in the long run the Phillips curve is therefore vertical (i.e. no exploitable trade-off between inflation and unemployment).
There would be much more to write about the Phillips curve issue and related variations on the theme (like, for example, the ā€œexpectations augmented Phillips curveā€), but for our purposes we just needed to introduce the basic concept as it represents an outstanding example of ā€œinterventionistā€ policies on the part of the state at the moment in which Robert Lucas began to work on what came to represent his most influential piece of research: the Lucasā€™ (1976) critique.
Focusing on econometric models, what Lucas argued was that the ā€œsimulations made using these models can, in principle, provide no useful information as to the actual consequences of alternative economic policiesā€. The reason for this is identified by Lucas in the fact that after a policy change is introduced, households and firms ā€œrecalculateā€ the parameters governing the structural dynamics of the economy and optimize accordingly. So, using the simulations for the effect of a policy change parameter that is estimated before the policy change actually occurs is essentially deprived of any significance. And no simulation can forecast accurately the effects of ā€œinterventionistā€ policies.
Almost simultaneously with the Lucasā€™ critique, the inadequacy of active macroeconomic policies was also forcefully highlighted by Robert J. Barro (1974) with special reference...

Table of contents