Sustainable Products
eBook - ePub

Sustainable Products

Life Cycle Assessment, Risk Management, Supply Chains, Eco-Design

Michael Has

Share book
  1. 243 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Sustainable Products

Life Cycle Assessment, Risk Management, Supply Chains, Eco-Design

Michael Has

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

Sustainable production presented from an overarching perspective. The book provides information on the identification and assessment of footprints, concepts of sustainability practice in manufacturing companies, stakeholder management and communication. For the reader



  • practical examples permit the analysis of the current situation and emerging developments.




  • the current technical status of footprint analysis according to the Green House Gas Protocol is displayed.




  • case studies with a focus on the manufacturing industry are discussed.


Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Sustainable Products an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Sustainable Products by Michael Has in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Tecnología e ingeniería & Ingeniería mecánica. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Publisher
De Gruyter
Year
2022
ISBN
9783110767391

Chapter 1 Historical development and basic ideas

What can be observed in the present is based on roots, some of which go far back into history. Patterns and concepts are also often repeated. Approaches developed during the industrial revolution, for example, led to prosperity (at least for many in some regions of the world), often had long-lasting success and, like all success, came at a price. Finding a starting point for a historical discussion is subjective, regardless of which viewpoint one takes; furthermore, there is no ONE starting point. Without claiming to be exhaustive, this first chapter is intended to give an overview of relevant historical contexts. The following is about pointing out certain lines of development and relating them to their consequences to the modern world. It will therefore not proceed in the form of a strict historical sequence.
For this brief historical review, we will start with James Watts and his invention of the steam engine. His idea became one of the starting points of the industrial revolution, as it enabled the exploitation of natural resources in the context of industrial production. Arnold Toynbee used the term industrial revolution to describe the economic development of Britain from 1760 to 1840 (although the term industrial revolution was used earlier by French writers). It refers to the process of change from a partially circular agricultural and craft economy to a linear economy dominated by industry and machine manufacturing [37]. The term linear economy today relates to the way resources were harvested and wasted would be called a cradle-to-grave economy, today: Resources are harvested, used, consumed and subsequently become waste. The main features of the industrial revolution were technological, socio-economic and cultural. Technological changes were given in Table 1.1.
Table 1.1:Technological changes during the industrial revolution according to [37].
(1) The use of new basic materials, mainly iron and steel – and more recently information
(2) The use of new sources of energy, both fuel and motive power, such as coal, the steam engine, electricity, petroleum and the internal combustion engine
(3) The invention of new machines that allows higher production with less human energy
(4) A new organisation of labour, known as the factory system, involved an increasing division of labour and specialisation of functions
(5) Important developments in transportation and communications, including the steam engine locomotive and steamship
(6) The increasing application of science to industry
When speaking of the second, third or fourth industrial revolution, the intention is to refer to the renewed change in one or more of these parameters in an economic context. These changes enabled and caused a sudden increase in access to resources, their use and, in the context of specialisation the existence of an international trade network, subsequently the mass production and consumption of goods. Expanded resource use, specialisation and mass production necessarily imply centralisation and this in turn implies a need for transport. Centralisation and transport characterise large economies to this day.
Political or economic power structures were initially unaffected by the technological and industrial development. During the time of the industrial revolution, in the third quarter of the eighteenth century, Adam Smith developed the idea of the “invisible hand” – referring to the self-regulating mechanisms in stable economic systems. In his 1776 work An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations [38], he used this idea again to describe the tendency of free markets to self-regulate. According to Smith, the influencing forces that determine market mechanisms are competition, supply, demand and self-interest. Ultimately, self-regulation is about the stability of the economic system to ensure that it delivers the maximum value possible from the point of view of the agents.
To this day, the idea of self-regulation as proposed by Smith is discussed very controversially: In particular, there is one aspect to pay attention to – Smith did not introduce nature as a limited resource as one of the forces involved in self-regulation. Taking today’s point of view, this would have made sense, as such a view would have helped to draw attention to dangers emanating from an overexploitation of nature, that is, non-sustainable action.
These concepts were not new at the time: In this context, it should be pointed out that sustainability-like concepts were already known at the time of Smith, for example, the corresponding German term “Nachhaltigkeit” was used as early as 1713 by Hans Carl von Carlowitz (1645–1714) to describe the need to preserve natural forests for future generations in view of the shortage of the resource wood.
But the school of thought based on Smith’s thinking did not take into account the environmental problems at hand. This was because the need for a stable nature/environment was not seen as a necessary part of the forces influencing the economy; the pre-Romantic period viewed nature merely as a backdrop, not as an economic asset. Although becoming less dominant, the mindset that a free market does not care about the environment can still be seen as more or less mainstream today. Times are changing, however – today it is undisputed that value can be ascribed to the stability of the natural environment. This thinking has prevailed in recent decades.
In this context, market regulation has also been accepted to address environmental concerns through conservative thinking.
The Reagan administration, certainly not to be seen as representing a left-wing movement, countered the desire to build new nuclear power plants with an argument that fits well with Adam Smith’s theory:
If such a plant was safe, the thinking went, then it should be commercially insured. The risk to the environment associated with the operation of a nuclear power plant or nuclear waste repository should not be borne by the general public, but by the owner of the respective power plant. Consequently, the price of such insurance should be added to the price of the electricity produced – an argument which contributed to the reasons why the further expansion of nuclear energy in the USA was subsequently halted.
Although this can be seen as promising from the perspective of nature as a resource, there is no general trend here: In the USA, too, the risk of final destruction of land associated with uranium mining and initial processing was accepted – the so-called National Sacrifice Areas (zones) were declared to state that the respective area may no longer be used by humans. The idea that nature provides value and should therefore be cared for only became the subject of theoretical and political considerations later on (see Chapter 4).
Thomas Malthus published An Essay on the Principle of Population around 1800 [39]. He stated:
I think I can justly state two postulates:
First, that food is necessary to the existence of man.
Secondly, that the passion between the sexes is necessary, and will remain almost in its present state.
From this Malthus derived two conclusions, namely,
  1. the food supply grows at an arithmetical (linear) rate, and
  2. population growth occurs at a geometric (exponential) rate.
In turn, he concluded that if the population grows faster than the required food supply, natural controls such as famines and wars will reduce the population to a sustainable level.
Malthus was publishing his insights at the brink of the industrial revolution in England. In the centuries before his lifetime, frequent and widespread famines were the norm. His theory was revolutionary because it explained conclusively why these famines had to occur. Malthus predicted that the next great famine would occur in the then coming decades. But it did not. The European population did not grow as Malthus predicted, and furthermore, improvements in agricultural technology (especially Liebig’s observations that led to the development of fertilisers) allowed food supplies to grow more steadily than expected.
Malthus’ thoughts were crucial for later thinkers such as Ricardo, Marx or Darwin; indeed, his theses continue ...

Table of contents