Mine!
eBook - ePub

Mine!

How the Hidden Rules of Ownership Control Our Lives

Michael Heller, James Salzman

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Mine!

How the Hidden Rules of Ownership Control Our Lives

Michael Heller, James Salzman

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

'A delicious book.' Jared Diamond Who controls the space around an aeroplane seat: you or the person behind you trying to work on their laptop? Who owns your favourite football player? And why do Facebook and Google want your private data?In Mine! Michael Heller and James Salzman reveal the hidden economic and social rules that guide everyday life, demonstrating that much of what we assume about ownership is wrong. Whether a lost wallet, a playground swing or a London flat, Mine! explores what ownership means and why it governs everything we do.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Mine! an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Mine! by Michael Heller, James Salzman in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Law & Intellectual Property Law. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2021
ISBN
9781786497802

Chapter 1

FIRST COME, LAST SERVED

Line-Standers

The best free show in Washington, D.C. is the Supreme Court. The courtroom is both ornate and intimate. You sit only steps from the justices of the highest court in the land and listen to America’s top advocates. This is democracy at its best, open and accessible to all. If you want to witness the fate of abortion, gun control, or religious freedom, you can. But you need to get there early—there are on average fewer than one hundred seats available for the public, and admission is first come, first served.
For high-profile cases, people arrive a day or more ahead of time, armed with camping chairs, sleeping bags, ponchos, and extra batteries for their smartphones. Folks in line tend to look out for one another—Supreme Court police officers refuse to monitor the line. If you have to go to the bathroom, those around you will hold your place. And they will also be on guard for people cutting in or adding friends. If someone does that, they are harangued with cries of “no cutting” and “back of the line.”
As the time to enter the Court approaches, though, a strange thing happens. Many of the disheveled people nearest the front of the line exchange their spots with gray-suited men and women. A little later the well-dressed enter the courtroom and take the best seats while those farther back in the line are not even admitted. What is going on?
Welcome to the line-standing business. Companies are paying line-standers, sometimes homeless people, to arrive days ahead, secure a spot at the front, and then wait and wait and wait. At the last minute, by the Court entrance etched with the words equal justice under law, the line-standers give way to paying clients who have the money to get in first but not the time or patience to wait. Small start-ups like Linestanding.com, Skip the Line, and Washington Express charge clients up to $6,000 for a “free” seat, while paying minimum wage to the hired line-standers who wait in the rain and cold.
Line-standing companies have transformed how seats become mine not just for Supreme Court arguments but also for open congressional hearings where the nation’s laws are debated. Hearing rooms used to be free to anyone willing to wait to see their elected representatives in action. Now those hearings are often packed with lawyers and lobbyists, all of whom paid, none of whom waited. The same transformation is happening in lines for new passports at the local federal building or building permits at City Hall.
Paid line-standers are a booming business in the private sector as well. If you’re willing to pay, you can get to the front for new iPhones at Apple stores, hot skatewear apparel at Supreme, rush Broadway show tickets, or even prime spots on New York City streets to watch the Macy’s Thanksgiving Day Parade. One line-stander employed by SOLD (Same Ole Line Dudes), a line-standing start-up, waited forty-three hours holding a spot so a client could be sure to get an audition for Shark Tank, the hit reality TV show for start-ups. Odds are that Robert Samuel, the entrepreneurial founder of SOLD, would have done better on the show than the guy from Colorado who paid Samuel for his place in line.
The same transition is happening online. The musical Hamilton was continuously sold out on Broadway for years after it opened. The producers of the show made most tickets available on a first-in-time basis on their website. The problem was that tech-savvy scalpers created computer programs—bots—that bought up all the tickets the microsecond they became available. As a result, the artists and producers earned only the tickets’ face value while fans paid scalpers’ premiums, often a multiple of the original price, on sites such as StubHub. Many weeks ticket scalpers earned more from Hamilton than did the producers and artists who put on the show. What good is the first-in-time rule if a bot will always jump the line faster than a mortal with a mouse? When Hamilton tried to outsmart the scalpers by making some tickets available only at the theater box office, companies like SOLD hired line-standers to snag them.
Bruce Springsteen tried another approach when he played his sold-out run on Broadway. He paired with TicketMaster as it debuted Verified Fan, an online system that aimed to circumvent the bots and line-standers and get at least some tickets directly to prescreened real fans. But even those tickets often ended up on the resale market—you have to be quite committed to the Boss to turn down a $10,000 offer for an $850 ticket.
How should we think about this rapid rise of paying to get to the head of the line?
For many, this transformation seems deeply unfair and undemocratic. One disappointed woman stood for days in line at the Supreme Court and still did not get to hear the 2015 case establishing the right to same-sex marriage. The real system, she said, is “Let’s pay the poor Black guys to hold the line for rich white people.” On the other hand, maybe line-standing should be viewed as a good thing—capitalism at its best, creating new jobs where none existed before, both for programmers scripting their bots and for the poor and homeless waiting in lines.
We never used to ask these questions. But today we must, because first-in-time is being dismantled from within.

Who’s on First?

For most of human history, for most resources, the rule for establishing original ownership followed a maxim expressed in ancient Roman law as “Whoever is earlier in time is stronger in right.” In other words, First come, first served.
This has long been the practice in families. Think back to your childhood Bible lessons. Why did Jacob put an animal skin on his arm to trick his blind father, Isaac, into thinking he was blessing Esau, Jacob’s rough-skinned brother? Esau was born first and by right should have received his father’s gifts. Being first got you not only paternal blessings but also earthly treasure. Jacob’s trickery let him jump the line.
The practice of primogeniture, inheritance by the firstborn son, has long decided the succession of royal families around the world. It still does today, with an egalitarian twist in countries such as Sweden and the Netherlands, which now pass the crown to the monarch’s firstborn child rather than just the first son.
First-in-time governed colonial exploration as well. Colonies in the New World were carved up among the European powers based on which nation’s explorer was first to plant his sovereign’s flag. This may hold some intuitive appeal for uninhabited lands, but what about places with people already living there? If being first is what counts, surely Native Americans had the stronger claim for owning America. Not so, said the international law of the time—as written by the European powers. When Europeans came to America, they defined first to mean “the first Christian discoverer.”
And here lies a key to understanding this ancient maxim for making things mine. Even something as factual-sounding as “who’s first” is not self-defining. The right question is “Who decides who’s first?” In American law, the answer is “The conqueror prescribes its limits,” according to Chief Justice John Marshall in Johnson v. M’Intosh, an 1823 Supreme Court decision that most lawyers read during their early days in law school. Being the first Christian European was what justified, as a matter of law, the claims of Spain to the Caribbean, Texas, Mexico, and California; of France to New Orleans, Canada, and much of middle America; and of England to New England and Virginia.
But if that’s the case, why did the world not rise in protest when Neil Armstrong planted the American flag on the moon in July 1969? That should have made the moon just as much a U.S. territory as early America was a European one. The answer is that by the 1960s, countries had renounced discovery and conquest as the basis for deciding who was first. In 1967 the United States, along with the Soviet Union and dozens of other countries, signed the U.N. Outer Space Treaty explicitly rejecting first-in-time for extraterrestrial resources.
So when Armstrong became the first human on the moon, he was not asserting American ownership there. Indeed, to make America’s intentions clear, in 1969 Congress felt compelled to pass a law stating that when a U.S. astronaut places a flag on the moon, it is “intended as a symbolic gesture of national pride in achievement and is not to be construed as a declaration of national appropriation by claim of sovereignty.”
Countries continue to play the “who’s on first” game, though, with contested results. In 2007 the Russian Navy tweaked the international community by placing a small titanium Russian flag on the bottom of the Arctic Ocean. Russia was symbolically staking a claim to the mineral-rich seabed beneath the North Pole and the trade shipping routes that cross the pole—all newly accessible because of climate change and melting ice. Though an international furor erupted over the idea that Russia might win these resources simply by flagging them first, the strategy is time-tested. As we shall see in Chapter 4, China is now implementing a version of this strategy by building and claiming islands in the South China Sea.
Territorial claims and family inheritances are not the only venues for first-in-time. Being first is also the default rule for how ordinary people claim all sorts of unowned things. It was how miners staked claims during the 1848 Gold Rush in California. In 1889, Native lands in Oklahoma were opened for pioneer settlement through “land runs” that began with a pistol shot on the state line. (Sooner was the derogatory term for those who jumped the gun.) Today well-funded start-ups are aiming to mine the moon and harpoon asteroids for water, platinum, and gold—all in tension with internationally recognized ownership rules. This is also the origin story of Uber, Airbnb, YouTube, and many other Internet businesses that raced ahead of the law to create and then capture markets. Ambiguity about ownership favors the bold, the heedless, the outlaws—those who race ahead first.
But not always.
The law looks not only to who is making the claim but also to what they are doing with it. In the 1800s, homesteaders not only had to arrive first at their 160-acre parcel of earth but also had to show that they cut, burned, fenced, planted, and wrenched sustenance from it continuously for a period of years. This was another reason courts of the day ruled that Native Americans did not own their ancestral lands. Europeans imagined Native peoples treading lightly through the forest while hunting fish and game and did not view that labor as sufficiently productive to sustain an original claim of ownership. They defined first to mean first to labor according to the agricultural and commercial ethos of the settlers.
What is first turns out to be a slippery concept—never just an empirical fact, always a legal construct. In the classic children’s book The Little Prince, we encounter a businessman counting stars. The little prince asks why and hears, “I own the stars, because nobody else before me ever thought of owning them.” But being the first to think of owning stars does not necessarily make them owned. By and large, courts and governments define and redefine what’s first to guide people invisibly and inexorably toward particular, socially approved forms of interaction with scarce resources.
Almost all the 1.3 million lawyers in America learned this insight by reading Pierson v. Post, a case about a fox-hunting dispute from 1805. Lodowick Post was riding horseback with his dogs while hunting down a fox, described by the Court as a “wild and noxious beast,” on unclaimed “waste land”—that is, a beach. In the last moments of the chase, after the fox had been exhausted, a man named Pierson appeared on the scene, easily killed the fox, and carried it away. Post sued, claiming Pierson had taken his property—the fox was Post’s because he had hunted it first and was on the verge of making the kill. (Note: it’s always worth asking who is suing. Who goes to court over one fox pelt or a rocking chair? Litigants are often deviants. Life is short. Work it out.)
So who wins? The law was silent. The judges all agreed that the first-in-time rule should convert the wild animal into something owned. But what counted as first? Here the judges split on one of the big divides of ownership design: whether to apply a bright-line rule or a standard. Bright-line rules define precise terms that tend to be predictable and easy to apply across a range of cases. Standards offer general guides that allow for fine-grained judgments and can lead to fairer outcomes in particular cases. Think of the difference between highway signs that say speed limit 55 and drive safely under the circumstances.
The majority of the judges wanted a bright-line rule. They did not want disappointed hunters in court arguing the fine points of the chase. So they created what became known as the rule of capture and decided for Pierson, the “saucy intruder.” The fox belongs to whoever “mortally wounds the wild animal and brings it under certain control.” Being first means finishing the job—not thinking about the fox or even chasing it around.
In dissent, one judge asserted that first should be defined to mean whatever maximizes the destruction of the “wily quadrupeds.” For him, the way to achieve that goal would be to ask if Post had a “reasonable prospect” of capture—an open-ended standard. Because he thought Post had such a prospect, Post was first and owned the fox. This makes a sort of intuitive sense: what was the point of investing in horses and hounds if, at the last minute, a random passerby could scoop up the fox exhausted by your chase?
So what happened after Pierson won? Did fox hunting grind to a halt? No—just the opposite. It turned out that in a first-to-capture world, hunters stepped up their game. Time has shown that the majority’s bright-line rule turbocharges innovations in capture technology, and not just for fox hunting. If you want to be first to own any wild animal, you had better adopt the most lethal methods. And this hunting rule was extended by analogy to many other natural resources. In many parts of America, if you want to own flowing underground resources—water, oil, gas—you have to innovate to ensure that you actually pump them out first.
Today the same is true for ownership of inventions. For two centuries, America used a version of a reasonable prospect rule, giving patent monopolies to those first to invent—an open-ended standard that led to much litigation. Then in 2011 America switched to a bright-line first to file rule: regardless of how much progress competing inventors made, the patent went to whoever won the race to the Patent Office. America was the last country in the world to adopt the rule of capture for patents, following a debate in Congress that substantially tracked the majority and dissenting views in P...

Table of contents