Victory for Hire
eBook - ePub

Victory for Hire

Private Security Companies' Impact on Military Effectiveness

Molly Dunigan

Share book
  1. 256 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  4. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Victory for Hire

Private Security Companies' Impact on Military Effectiveness

Molly Dunigan

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

At peak utilization, private security contractors (PSCs) constituted a larger occupying force in Iraq and Afghanistan than did U.S. troops. Yet, no book has so far assessed the impact of private security companies on military effectiveness. Filling that gap, Molly Dunigan reveals how the increasing tendency to outsource missions to PSCs has significant ramifications for both tactical and long-term strategic military effectiveness—and for the likelihood that the democracies that deploy PSCs will be victorious in warfare, both over the short- and long-term.

She highlights some of the ongoing problems with deploying large numbers of private security contractors alongside the military, specifically identifying the deployment scenarios involving PSCs that are most likely to have either positive or negative implications for military effectiveness. She then provides detailed recommendations to alleviate these problems. Given the likelihood that the U.S. will continue to use PSCs in future contingencies, this book has real implications for the future of U.S. military and foreign policy.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Victory for Hire an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Victory for Hire by Molly Dunigan in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Politica e relazioni internazionali & LibertĂ  politica. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

1 INTRODUCTION
AS OF DECEMBER 31, 2007, at least 1,123 private contractors working for the U.S. government or U.S. companies in Iraq had been killed, according to the U.S. Department of Labor. Private contractors constituted the largest occupying force in Iraq during this time period, outnumbering even U.S. forces, with roughly 155,000 contractors employed there as of February 2008.1 Contractors operating in Iraq have come from around the globe, ranging from citizens of English-speaking countries such as the United States, United Kingdom, Australia, and New Zealand, to contractors from countries such as Chile or Fiji that were not directly involved in the conflict (third-country nationals, or TCNs), to local Iraqis (local nationals, or LNs). Of the DoD contractors, approximately 10,422 were security contractors as of March 2009, although estimates of the numbers of security contractors employed by all entities in Iraq had ranged as high as 30,000 at earlier points in the conflict.2 This study is primarily concerned with this subgroup of contractors, the armed security contractors, at least insofar as the Iraq case is concerned.
In Afghanistan, meanwhile, the number of DoD contractors was substantially higher than the number of U.S. troops as of March 2009, with 68,197 contractors compared to 52,300 uniformed military personnel. Again, this does not take into account the number of non-DoD contractors employed in Afghanistan during this period, so the ratio was likely quite a bit higher than these numbers reflect. Nonetheless, these figures reportedly represented the highest recorded percentage of contractors used by the Department of Defense in any conflict in the history of the United States, with contractors comprising 57 percent of the DoD workforce in Afghanistan during this period.3
Such a story would have been unimaginable thirty years earlier, when superpower competition fueled national militaries. Not until the fall of the Soviet Union and the corresponding “Peace Dividend” were national militaries— particularly the U.S. military—downsized to the extent that outsourcing of non-core military tasks would be deemed acceptable and necessary. Indeed, it was during the Reagan and Thatcher eras that the economic logic and culture of outsourcing government functions gained prominence. Neoliberal economic thinking and government reports throughout the 1980s and 1990s on the cost-saving benefits of privatization and outsourcing led to the development and expansion of private companies that could provide all non-core military services for the troops, leaving the skilled war fighters free to perform the actual combat tasks. These companies provided services such as weapons system maintenance and upkeep, supply transport, cooking, cleaning, and base construction, among many others.
The industry expanded when former U.S. and U.K. military officers, particularly from the Special Forces, built on the legacy of 1960s British and 1980s South African officers in developing the notion of the “private security company” (PSC)—a company that would provide armed bodyguards and convoy security services for various actors in high-risk areas of operation. Former British Special Air Services (SAS) Colonel David Stirling formed the first of the modern private military companies, WatchGuard International, in Britain in 1967. The firm employed former SAS personnel to train the militaries of the sultanates of the Persian Gulf, to provide support for their operations against rebel movements and internal dissidents, and eventually to provide military advisory training teams to clients in the Middle East, Africa, Latin America, and East Asia.
WatchGuard became the model for all future private military companies, and several other British private military companies grew out of this model in the next few decades, including Kulinda Security Ltd., KAS Enterprises, KMS (“Keenie Meenie Services”), Saladin Security, and Defence Systems Ltd. (DSL). Then, in 1989, a member of the South African Defence Force—Luther Eeben Barlow—formed Executive Outcomes (EO). Executive Outcomes operated in conflicts throughout the African continent during the 1990s, most notably in Angola, Sierra Leone, Congo, and Burundi. Executive Outcomes was disbanded in 1999, but many former EO officers went on to form their own private military firms, including Alpha 5, Stabilco, Omega Support Ltd., Panasec Corporate Dynamics, and Southern Cross Security.4
To distinguish themselves from the less reputable private military companies that operated mainly in African states in the 1980s and early 1990s, modern private security companies are adamant that they provide only defensive services and will not fight offensively or for non-democratic causes. The United States and its allies used private military firms in both the 1990–1991 Iraq War and the Balkans conflicts in the mid-1990s, but the majority of the companies involved in these conflicts were employed to perform logistical functions, not security services. Notably, the United States and its allies employed many fewer contractors in these conflicts than they do in the current wars in Iraq and Afghanistan. The rapid expansion of the private security industry over the past several years is unprecedented in modern times, as is the current practice in Iraq and Afghanistan of deploying private security personnel in large numbers on the ground alongside coalition forces. This is particularly true because today’s private security personnel are not formally integrated into the military structure, as is the case with, for instance, French Foreign Legion troops and the French military. Security contractors’ position in the military chain of command is therefore constantly in question, which, among other things, leads to a host of potential PSC–military coordination problems.
The privatizing reforms of the 1980s and 1990s that preceded this rapid expansion of the private security industry were designed to make government operations more efficient. Yet some media and governmental reports portray such privatization, when applied to the military sphere, as having actually decreased military effectiveness. This book therefore addresses the puzzle of why reforms that were intended to increase performance may be serving instead to decrease it. The book expands its theoretical inquiry beyond the issue of military effectiveness, however, to examine the ramifications of security privatization for the likelihood that democracies will be victorious in their conflicts.5 I examine the impact of private security forces on military effectiveness in three different types of situations: instances of PSC–military co-deployment, such as the current Iraq War; instances of PSC deployment in place of military deployment; and historical cases in which mercenary forces other than PSCs are structurally integrated in a manner similar to, or are actually integrated into, regular military forces. In using these cases to probe this puzzle, the book has two interrelated goals. The first is to compare different situations of privatized force employment, to illustrate PSCs’ potential effects on military effectiveness and on the likelihood that democracies will be victorious in their conflicts. The second is to understand the different effects of structure and identity on the effectiveness of military forces composed of national armies combined with PSCs, with an eye to providing policy prescriptions for current U.S. policy.
Of primary importance to PSCs’ impact on military effectiveness, I argue, are the following: (1) the structural integration of private security contractors into the military forces with which they are deployed; (2) the cohesiveness of the collective identities of private and national military forces deployed together; and (3) the extent to which private security companies and their personnel operate in an ethical manner, complying with the rules and norms of international humanitarian law. In exploring the three different types of cases mentioned above, I conclude that private forces tend to decrease military effectiveness and prospects for the democratic advantage in modern cases of PSC–military co-deployment due to a combination of these structural, identity, and ethical issues. Meanwhile, PSCs often increase the military effectiveness of host nation forces in situations in which they are deployed in place of intervening military forces, yet decrease the chances that the methods of operational behavior are performed with due respect for established legal norms and decrease the prospects for the democratic advantage due to their impact on states’ conflict selectivity. Interestingly, however, PSCs do not appear in such instances to have a better impact on the host nation forces’ military effectiveness than would the regular militaries of democratic intervening states, as indicated by several counterfactual comparison cases in which no PSC was deployed. Furthermore, it appears that if covert PSC activities are revealed to the democratic electorate, a public outcry can result on a scale similar to the outcry that occurs when direct government or state-sponsored military involvement in covert activities is revealed to the public. Finally, PSCs both increase and decrease military effectiveness in historical situations of mercenary forces deployed with national militaries and consistently put ethical force employment at risk, due to a combination of structural and identity-based factors.
While it is hoped that professional, policy, and academic audiences will find these conclusions and this research to be compelling, these different audiences will likely find different aspects of this work to be useful. Policymakers and military professionals who may take for granted that PSCs are here to stay will likely be most interested in the study’s recommendations for how to use PSCs most effectively. Those who are more skeptical of the value of PSCs, however, will likely be most interested in two notable implications of the findings elaborated in the following chapters. First, this latter audience will find in the evidence outlined throughout the study a strong critique of the democratic peace hypothesis, as the forthcoming chapters indicate that PSCs can be and are indeed used by democratic policymakers—often in a covert fashion—to avoid accountability to the citizenry for decisions to go to war. Even though covert PSC activities can sometimes be unintentionally revealed to the public, such an implication bodes poorly for PSCs’ impact on global efforts to create and sustain a peaceful international system.6 Second, an audience skeptical of the value of PSCs will note that Chapter 6’s prescription for greater regulatory oversight is a potentially costly recommendation that could ultimately render PSCs relatively uneconomical.
CONTEXT OF OUTSOURCING
The turn to private military and security forces would be impossible if much of the world—driven by a desire for cost savings and improved outcomes— had not already embraced a larger ideological shift toward privatization and the outsourcing of a range of government functions, including the exercise of coercive power and violence. Governments and leaders across the globe have relied on mercenaries and other private forces to supplement or replace their own militaries throughout history. Yet the outsourcing of violence in modern times expands beyond traditional mercenarism and occurs according to both a logic of capacity (that is, the need to fill the demand for forces) and a normative logic.
In many cases, governments have insufficient numbers of soldiers and/or are reluctant to institute a policy of conscription, causing leaders to look elsewhere for the forces necessary to defend the state and carry out the military elements of state policy. As Gil Merom notes with regard to the limitations imposed on democratic leaders by having to institute a policy of conscription, “Those most likely and best able to check the president’s war powers would not do so unless they had a personal stake . . . there is ‘no representation without taxation.’”7 Hence—despite the fact that democracies may have the political legitimacy to assemble mass armies with reduced resort to coercion—the potential to out-source violence and military functions offers a way for democratic leaders to handle problems of military capacity without having to impose policies of conscription, thus increasing their electoral prospects. In other words, outsourcing occurs in such instances to bolster the capacity of existing forces. This happens, for instance, with U.N. peacekeeping missions, which are outsourced to small, decrepit state militaries such as the Fijian Army. As the Fiji Times notes:
Since the 1970s, this impoverished and remote remnant of the British empire has positioned itself as a discount-soldier surplus store. Its best customer has been the UN peacekeeping operations. Today, on the post-September 11 battlefield, Fiji is marketing for hire its 3,500 active soldiers, 15,000 reservists and more than 20,000 unemployed former troops.8
Such outsourcing practices have a long historical trajectory. Egypt began outsourcing its war-making activities to mercenaries in 1479 BCE, substituting mercenaries for citizen armies for the next 700 years. The Egyptians actively recruited mercenaries from North Africa (the Nubians) and from tribes in the Aegean Islands and along the Anatolian Coast. Both supply and demand dictated this increase in the use of hired soldiers, as Egyptian citizens preferred to avoid the battlefield and enjoy their riches, and large numbers of poor and/or displaced tribes were simultaneously available to fight for money.9 The Israelites, meanwhile, hired soldiers from foreign lands so that local citizens would be free to maintain the economic output necessary to support both the kingdom and the army. The Hebrews began this practice around 1250 BCE. Although David steadily decreased Israel’s reliance on foreign soldiers after he assumed power around 925 BCE, Israel never completely stopped hiring mercenaries.10
The Roman Empire also relied on mercenaries to bolster the capacity of its existing forces.11 When the effects of the Second Punic War on the Italian countryside forced small farmers to sell their land to wealthy landowners and migrate to the cities for menial jobs, poor citizens began to feel distanced from the empire and thus reluctant to risk their lives in the military. Meanwhile, their wealthy counterparts were similarly reluctant to join the military, preferring instead to stay at home and enjoy their wealth.12 Rome’s expansion therefore outgrew its capacity to staff its military with professional soldiers in the fourth century, and the empire was forced to hire mercenaries to keep up with this demand for soldiers.13
More recently, both mercenaries and privateers played a critical role in supplementing existing forces in the American Revolution. The British government signed treaties with six German princes in 1776 for the provision of a total of almost 30,000 German soldiers to help fight the colonial uprising in America. Landgrave Frederick II of Hesse-Cassel provided the vast majority of these soldiers, and thus the entire deployed German force was commonly referred to as a Hessian force.14 The Hessian mercenaries served as British auxiliary forces, fully integrated into the British military system.
On the American side of the conflict, American colonists commissioned approximately 700 ships to fight against the British. These privateers—ships licensed by the Americans to harass British vessels and confiscate their cargoes—bolstered the American sea presence considerably, fighting alongside the American Navy’s 100 ships. Both Thomas Paine and General George Washington owned stock in privateers.15 These private ships also played a large role on both the American and British sides in the War of 1812. Congress even granted legal sanction to privateers during this period. With a few extra cannon and men, therefore, any merchant vessel was easily converted into a privateer.16
Outsourcing under the logic of capacity has similarly occurred in Operation Iraqi Freedom and Operation Enduring Freedom in Afghanistan, primarily due to the expanding definition of what constitutes “warfare” in U.S. military and policy circles. The growing tendency to consider stability, security, transition, and reconstruction (SSTR) missions as an integral component of warfare stretches the U.S. military and coalition forces thin, causing U.S. policymakers to rely on private security companies as an ad hoc supplement to regular military forces. The practice of outsourcing violence has become so commonplace in U.S. policy that the DoD now publicly recognizes the private security industry’s primacy in developing current notions of warfare. Stability, security, transition, and reconstruction missions are now defined as a core U.S. military activity, one in which the DoD explicitly acknowledges that the private sector must play a defining role. Department of Defense Directive 3000.05 now formally includes the private sector in the emerging Pentagon policies pertaining to SSTR missions:
It is DoD policy that stability operations are a core U.S. military mission that the Department of Defense shall be prepared to conduct and support. They shall be given priority comparable to combat operations and be explicitly addressed and integrated across all DoD activities including doctrine, organizations, training, education, exercises, materiel, leadership, personnel, facilities, and planning.17
This document further indicates that:
Many stability operations tasks are best performed by indigenous, foreign, or U.S. civilian professionals . . . Military-civilian teams are a critical U.S. Government stability operations tool. The Department of Defense shall continue to lead and support the development of military-civilian teams . . . Participation in such teams shall be open to . . . members of the Private Sector [including private sector individuals and for-profit companies] with relevant skills and expertise.18
The explicit connecti...

Table of contents