Globalization of Water
eBook - ePub

Globalization of Water

Sharing the Planet's Freshwater Resources

Arjen Y. Hoekstra, Ashok K. Chapagain

Compartir libro
  1. English
  2. ePUB (apto para móviles)
  3. Disponible en iOS y Android
eBook - ePub

Globalization of Water

Sharing the Planet's Freshwater Resources

Arjen Y. Hoekstra, Ashok K. Chapagain

Detalles del libro
Vista previa del libro
Índice
Citas

Información del libro

Globalization of Water is a first-of-its-kind review of the critical relationship between globalization and sustainable water management. It explores the impact of international trade on local water depletion and pollution and identifies "water dependent" nations.

  • Examines the critical link between water management and international trade, considering how local water depletion and pollution are often closely tied to the structure of the global economy
  • Offers a consumer-based indicator of each nation's water use: the water footprint
  • Questions whether trade can enhance global water use efficiency, or whether it simply shifts the environmental burden to a distant location
  • Highlights the hidden link between national consumption and the use of water resources across the globe, identifying the threats facing 'water dependent' countries worldwide
  • Provides a state-of-the-art review and in-depth data source for a new field of knowledge

Preguntas frecuentes

¿Cómo cancelo mi suscripción?
Simplemente, dirígete a la sección ajustes de la cuenta y haz clic en «Cancelar suscripción». Así de sencillo. Después de cancelar tu suscripción, esta permanecerá activa el tiempo restante que hayas pagado. Obtén más información aquí.
¿Cómo descargo los libros?
Por el momento, todos nuestros libros ePub adaptables a dispositivos móviles se pueden descargar a través de la aplicación. La mayor parte de nuestros PDF también se puede descargar y ya estamos trabajando para que el resto también sea descargable. Obtén más información aquí.
¿En qué se diferencian los planes de precios?
Ambos planes te permiten acceder por completo a la biblioteca y a todas las funciones de Perlego. Las únicas diferencias son el precio y el período de suscripción: con el plan anual ahorrarás en torno a un 30 % en comparación con 12 meses de un plan mensual.
¿Qué es Perlego?
Somos un servicio de suscripción de libros de texto en línea que te permite acceder a toda una biblioteca en línea por menos de lo que cuesta un libro al mes. Con más de un millón de libros sobre más de 1000 categorías, ¡tenemos todo lo que necesitas! Obtén más información aquí.
¿Perlego ofrece la función de texto a voz?
Busca el símbolo de lectura en voz alta en tu próximo libro para ver si puedes escucharlo. La herramienta de lectura en voz alta lee el texto en voz alta por ti, resaltando el texto a medida que se lee. Puedes pausarla, acelerarla y ralentizarla. Obtén más información aquí.
¿Es Globalization of Water un PDF/ePUB en línea?
Sí, puedes acceder a Globalization of Water de Arjen Y. Hoekstra, Ashok K. Chapagain en formato PDF o ePUB, así como a otros libros populares de Scienze fisiche y Geologia e scienze della terra. Tenemos más de un millón de libros disponibles en nuestro catálogo para que explores.

Información

Año
2011
ISBN
9781444360196
Chapter 1
Introduction
In the world of today, people in Japan indirectly affect the hydro-logical system in the USA and people in Europe indirectly impact on the regional water systems in Brazil. When you ask somebody how this can happen, the reply will most probably be: through climate change. This answer is likely because much has been reported about the expected effects of past and ongoing local emissions of greenhouse gases on future global temperature, evaporation, and precipitation patterns. Most people are aware that local emissions of greenhouse gases contribute to global climate change and can thus indirectly affect other locations. Little is known, however, about a second mechanism through which people affect water systems in other parts of the world. This second mechanism, which is as “invisible” as climate change but which is today already much more significant, is global trade. International trade in agricultural and industrial commodities creates a link between the demand for water-intensive commodities (notably crops) in countries like Japan, Italy, Germany, and the UK and the water use for production of these commodities in countries such as the USA and Brazil. Water use for producing export commodities for the global market significantly contributes to changes in local water systems. By buying crop products imported from the USA, Japanese consumers put pressure on the water resources of the latter, contributing to the mining of aquifers and emptying of rivers in North America. Well-documented examples are the mined Ogallala Aquifer and emptied Colorado River. European consumers contribute to a significant degree to the water demand in Brazil by buying water-intensive crop and livestock products imported from this country. Well known is the ongoing deforestation of the Amazonian rainforest with its implications for biodiversity, erosion, and runoff.
Though consensus seems to exist that the river basin is the appropriate unit for analyzing freshwater availability and use, in this book we argue that it is becoming increasingly important to put freshwater issues in a global context. Although other authors have already argued thus (Postel et al., 1996; Vo¨ro¨smarty et al., 2000), we add a new dimension to the argument. International trade in commodities implies long-distance transfers of water in virtual form, where virtual water is understood as the volume of water that has been used to produce a commodity and that is thus virtually embedded in it (Allan, 1998b). Knowledge about the virtual-water flows entering and leaving a country can cast a completely new light on the actual water scarcity of a country. For example, Jordan imports about 5 to 7 billion m3 of virtual water per year, which is in sharp contrast with the 1 billion m3 of water withdrawn annually from domestic water sources (Haddadin, 2003; Chapagain and Hoekstra, 2004). This means that people in Jordan apparently survive owing to the import of water-intensive commodities from elsewhere, for example the USA. Jordan’s water shortage is largely covered up by intelligent trade: export of goods and services that require little water and import of products that need a lot of water. The positive side of Jordan’s trade balance is that it preserves the scarce domestic water resources; the negative side is that the people are heavily “water dependent.” A different case is Egypt, a country which has not been willing to become water dependent and in which water self-sufficiency is high on the political agenda. However, with a total water withdrawal inside the country of 65billion m3/yr, Egypt still has an estimated net virtual-water import of 10 to 20billion m3/yr (Yang and Zehnder, 2002; Zimmer and Renault, 2003; Chapagain and Hoekstra, 2004). This means that even Egypt’s water balance is not immune to its pattern of international trade. In fact, there exist no countries in the world where the pattern of trade does not influence the pattern of domestic water use. Developing national water policies without explicitly considering the implications of international trade thus seems to be injudicious. Nevertheless, this is the common practice. In addition, formulating foreign trade policies in water-scarce countries without explicit consideration of domestic water resource availability would seem to be inadvisable as well. Yet, this is what generally happens.
In this book we address questions such as: Is it efficient to import water in virtual form if domestic water resources are scarce? And what are the implications of importing virtual water in terms of the resulting “water dependency”? But once we enter the area of “water and international trade” other questions also arise. If water-intensive products are imported from a distant location, the negative impacts of water use in the area of production will remain invisible for the consumer. Together with the fact that usually only a small fraction of the full cost of water use is included in the price of products, there is little incentive for consumers to change their consumption behavior or otherwise contribute to the mitigation of distant water problems. Thus new questions come up: What are the invisible tele-connections between intensive consumption of water-intensive products in some places on earth and the impacts of water use in other places? And does international trade in water-intensive commodities contribute to the unrestricted growth of consumption of water-intensive products in a world where water becomes increasingly scarce? In order to address these sorts of questions, we use in this book a number of novel concepts such as the “virtual-water content” of a commodity, the “water footprint” of a nation, and the “water saving” as a result of international trade. Let us introduce and explain these concepts one by one.
The virtual-water concept was introduced by Allan (1998a,b, 1999a,b, 2001) when he studied the possibility of importing virtual water (as opposed to real water) as a partial solution to problems of water scarcity in the Middle East. Allan elaborated the idea of using virtual-water import (coming along with food imports) as a tool to release the pressure on scarcely available domestic water resources. Virtual-water import thus becomes an alternative water source, alongside endogenous water sources. Imported virtual water has therefore also been called “exogenous water” (Haddadin, 2003).
The water-footprint concept was introduced by Hoekstra and Hung (2002) when they were looking for an indicator that could map the impact of human consumption on global freshwater resources. The concept was subsequently elaborated by the authors of this book (Chapagain and Hoekstra, 2004; Hoekstra and Chapagain, 2007a). The water footprint shows water use related to consumption within a nation, while the traditional indicator shows water use in relation to production within a nation. Traditionally, national water use has been measured as the total freshwater withdrawal for the various sectors of the economy. By contrast, the water footprint shows not only freshwater use within the country considered, but also freshwater use outside the country’s borders. It refers to all forms of freshwater use that contribute to the production of goods and services consumed by the inhabitants of a certain country. The water footprint of the Dutch community, for example, also refers to the use of water for rice production in Thailand (insofar as the rice is exported to the Netherlands for consumption there). Conversely, the water footprint of a nation excludes water that is used within the national territory for producing commodities for export, which are consumed elsewhere.
The water footprint of a nation consists of three components: blue, green, and gray components. The terms blue and green refer to the source of the water (Falkenmark, 2003). Green water use refers to the use of rainwater, while blue water use refers to use of ground-or surface water. Rain-fed agriculture is fully based on green water, while irrigated agriculture is based on a combination of green and blue water. The industrial and domestic sectors are generally fully based on blue water. The blue water footprint of a nation is the volume of freshwater that evaporated from global blue water resources (ground- and surface water) to produce the goods and services consumed by its inhabitants. The green water footprint is the volume of water evaporated from global green water resources (rainwater stored in the soil as soil moisture). We have expanded the water-footprint concept by including a third form of water use: water use as a result of pollution. We have proposed to quantify this “gray” water footprint by estimating the volume of water needed to dilute a certain amount of pollution such that it meets ambient water quality standards. We have elaborated this idea in the cotton study discussed in Chapter 9.
Active promotion of the import of virtual water in water-scarce countries is based on the idea that a nation can preserve its domestic water resources by importing a water-intensive product instead of producing it domestically. Import of virtual water thus leads to a “national water saving.” In addition to this, Oki and Kanae (2004) introduced the idea of a “global water saving.” International trade can save water globally when a water-intensive commodity is traded from an area where it is produced with high water productivity (low water input per unit of output) to an area with lower water productivity (high water input per unit of output). Conversely, there can be a “global water loss” if a water-intensive commodity is traded from an area with low water productivity to one with high water productivity. All studies of global water savings and losses as a result of international trade that have been carried out so far indicate that the net effect of current international trade is a global water saving (De Fraiture et al., 2004; Oki and Kanae, 2004; Chapagain et al., 2006a; Yang et al., 2006).
Since the International Expert Meeting on Virtual Water Trade, held in Delft, the Netherlands, in December 2002 (Hoekstra, 2003) and the special session on Virtual Water Trade and Geopolitics during the Third World Water Forum in Japan in March 2003, interest in the concepts of virtual water, water footprints, and global water saving has greatly increased. As a follow-up to the Water Forum in Japan, the World Water Council organized an e-conference on virtual-water trade and geopolitics (WWC, 2004). During three months in Fall 2003 about 300 people participated in a web-based debate about questions such as:
  • Does virtual-water trade contribute to the improvement of water availability and through that to local food security, livelihoods, environment, and local economy?
  • In which conditions should virtual-water trade be encouraged?
  • Does virtual water contribute to conflict resolution or will it increase tensions and conflict potential for those countries relying on trade?
  • What governance structures would be necessary to enable a fair virtual-water trade?
  • How can the concepts of virtual water and water footprints help in creating awareness about water consumption and saving water by modification of diet?
  • What is required from whom to progress on the appropriate and fair introduction and use of the virtual-water concept?
After the e-conference, different workshops addressing virtual-water trade and water footprints were organized: by Stanford University (November 2004, March 2005), the German Development Institute (Bonn, September 2005), the Fourth World Water Forum (Mexico City, March 2006), the Global Water System Project (Bonn, June 2006), and the Institute for Social-Ecological Research (Frankfurt, July 2006), amongst others. In addition, a considerable number of Master and PhD students from all parts of the world have started to devote their studies to the subject. Apparently the issue of “trade and water” has quite suddenly been recognized as a relevant policy concern and an interesting research field. This book aims to summarize our current knowledge in the field, a somewhat tricky effort given the continuous stream of new research results.
In Chapter 2 we discuss how one can assess the virtual-water content of a commodity and show the resulting estimates for various products. In Chapter 3 we explain how international virtual-water transfers can be quantified and draw the virtual-water balance for each country of the world. Chapter 4 shows how international trade can result in both national and global water savings, but can also occasionally result in global water losses. In Chapter 5 we describe how to assess the water footprint of a nation and show the resulting estimates for all nations of the world. Chapter 6 contains a case study for the Netherlands, a humid country, and Morocco, an arid–semi-arid country. In Chapter 7 we elaborate on the virtual-water transfers within China, which surprisingly go from the water-scarce north to the water-rich south. In Chapter 8 we show the water footprint of coffee and tea consumption, and in Chapter 9 we do a similar but more detailed exercise for cotton. Chapter 10 shows how international trade has made many countries heavily “water dependent” and how water has thus become a geopolitical resource. In the final chapter we explore what sorts of global institutional arrangements are needed to make sure that international trade contributes not only to efficiency in water use, but also to sustainable and equitable water use across the globe.
Chapter 2
How Much Water is Used for Producing our Goods and Services?
In 2003 Novib, the Dutch branch of Oxfam International, asked us to estimate the total volume of water that is used to produce one cup of coffee, and similarly for a cup of tea. The question was to trace the origins of the coffee and tea and estimate the volumes of water used in the various production phases. Although we did indeed look at the water uses during the whole production chain, it was clear from the beginning that the agricultural stage, the stage in which the coffee and tea plants grow and deliver their products, would turn out to be the most water consuming. We had to look at the various origins of coffee and tea, because water requirements in one place are different from those in another place. Focusing on coffee, we also had to translate water use per hectare at field level into water use per ton of coffee cherries yielded, and further into water use per ton of roasted coffee, and finally into water use per cup of coffee. In other words, we had to find out, per coffee-producing country, how many cups of coffee can be annually derived from one hectare and relate that to the water use per hectare. We found out that on average a cup of coffee requires 140 liters of water, mostly rainwater for growth of the coffee plant. Wherever we presented our finding, people had difficulty believing it. Of course we started to let friends, colleagues, and students guess first. It seldom occurred that somebody’s guess was even in the right order of magnitude. To some extent we have become famous for our magic number of 140 liters, because this is a nice little fact that people like to remember, to bring up at coffee conversation at work or wherever. Although most people think that we are clever for having calculated this number, some colleagues have also criticized us for misleading people by presenting a meaningless number. The essence of the critique was that even if we were right, what would it matter? Most of the water used for coffee, and also for tea, is rainwater, which comes for free, doesn’t it?
Later on we will argue that although water generally does indeed come for free, this does not mean it does not have a value. The amount of rainwater above land varies over time and from place to place, but the global annual volume is more or less constant and sets an upper level to annual freshwater use worldwide. As soon as water is scarce, it has a value (by economic definition). Also, rainwater has a value if there are competing uses that cannot be fulfilled simultaneously. An economist would say: when rainwater is applied for the production of one crop, the opportunity cost of the rainwater is equal to the value that it would have generated if it had been applied for the production of another, more valuable crop. At this point, however, we are not going to follow this line of argument. Instead, we will consider the water need for a few other commodities, to give some factual basis.
Virtual Water
But first some discussion about terminology. We are not unique in asking the question: How much of an input was necessary to produce something? Energy experts for example speak about the “embodied energy” of a good or service, referring to the amount of direct and indirect energy required to produce it (Herendeen, 2004). Similarly one could speak about the amount of land or labor required to make a product, which would then be called embodied land, embodied labor, etc. We could thus speak here about the volume of “embodied water” in a product. Tony Allan originally used the term “embedded water,” but since the concept was not well understood he later switched to “virtual water” (Allan, 2003). The term “virtual water” is often loosely defined as the water needed to produce a product. This definition refers to the water needed, which is not necessarily the same as the water actually used. The “water need” can be more or less than the actual water volume used, depending on the interpretation of what is needed. The concept of water need is hypothetical in nature and thus difficult to handle. We prefer to refer to the actual water volume used, which creates the possibility for empirical measurement and validation. In our own studies we apply the following definition: the “virtual-water content” of a product is the volume of water used to produce it, measured at the place(s) where it was actually produced. Some scholars, such as Taikan Oki from Japan, have argued that the virtual-water content of a product should be calculated not at the place of actual production but at the place of consumption (Oki and Kanae, 2004). The argument is that it is particularly useful to know how much water would have been required in the importing country if the goods had not been imported but produced domestically instead. In this philosophy, the term virtual water is therefore defined as “the water volume that would have been required if the product had been produced in the country of consumption.” Virtual water is here thus again a hypothetical need, not an actual volume, and thus difficult to establish empirically.
In our studies we stick to the idea of defining virtual-water content based on actual water use. Especially when we want to establish the water footprint of a nation we are most interested in the actual water use of the products consumed. For that purpose we need to know the virtual-water content of the products as they are in the producing countries. Only in Chapter 4, when discussing water savings in countries that import water in virtual form, will we come back to this issue, because we will then compare the water that would have been required in an importing country if the product had been produced domestically with the water that was actually used in the exporting country. In the remainder of the book we will follow the principle of measuring the virtual-water content of products at the place of production. The adjective “virtual” refers to the fact that most of the water used in the production is ultimately not contained within the product. The real-water content of products is generally negligible compared with the virtual-water content. The (global average) virtual-water content of wheat for instance is 1;300 m3/ton, while the real-water content is less than 1 m3/ton.
Although successful as a concept – most practitioners in the field of water scarcity management nowadays are familiar with it – the term “virtual water” has resulted in considerable confusion and debate. Scholars such as Stephen Merrett who do not approve of the concept like to joke about it as being virtual in itself (Merrett, 2003). Although we ourselves have contributed to the popularization of the concept, we acknowledge that the term, although apparently appealing to people’s imagination, is not very self-explanatory. Alternative terms that have been proposed are, however, not much better. The advantage of a term such as “embodied” or “embedded water” would be that it links up with the term “embodied energy” used in another branch of environmental studies. However, speaking about “embodied water” in a product is confusing in the sense that most of the water used to make a product will not literally be incorporated in the product. In fact the term “embodied water” suggests that it refers to the real-water content of a product, which as we have explained is quite different from its virtual-water content. Munther Haddadin, the former Minister of Water and Irrigation of Jordan, has used the term “exogenous water” as an alternative to “virtual water,” referring to the fact that importing water-intensive products can be regarded as an external source of water for the importing country (Haddadin, 2003). He has also used the term “shadow water” (Haddadin, 2006). Both terms have been inspired by the context in which they are used: the discourse on domestic water saving through import of water-intensive commodities. The terms are less useful in a more generic context where we simply want to refer to the volume of water used to produce a product. As it is, the most decisive argument for choosing the term “virtual water” in this book was that, if we had not done so, we would have deviated from what has become common in the world of water exper...

Índice