After Piketty
eBook - ePub

After Piketty

The Agenda for Economics and Inequality

Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, Marshall Steinbaum, Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, Marshall Steinbaum

Compartir libro
  1. English
  2. ePUB (apto para móviles)
  3. Disponible en iOS y Android
eBook - ePub

After Piketty

The Agenda for Economics and Inequality

Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, Marshall Steinbaum, Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, Marshall Steinbaum

Detalles del libro
Vista previa del libro
Índice
Citas

Información del libro

A Foreign Affairs Best Book of the Year "An intellectual excursion of a kind rarely offered by modern economics."
— Foreign Affairs Thomas Piketty's Capital in the Twenty-First Century is the most widely discussed work of economics in recent years. But are its analyses of inequality and economic growth on target? Where should researchers go from there in exploring the ideas Piketty pushed to the forefront of global conversation? A cast of leading economists and other social scientists—including Emmanuel Saez, Branko Milanovic, Laura Tyson, and Michael Spence—tackle these questions in dialogue with Piketty."A fantastic introduction to Piketty's main argument in Capital, and to some of the main criticisms, including doubt that his key equation…showing that returns on capital grow faster than the economy—will hold true in the long run."
— Nature "Piketty's work…laid bare just how ill-equipped our existing frameworks are for understanding, predicting, and changing inequality. This extraordinary collection shows that our most nimble social scientists are responding to the challenge."
—Justin Wolfers, University of Michigan

Preguntas frecuentes

¿Cómo cancelo mi suscripción?
Simplemente, dirígete a la sección ajustes de la cuenta y haz clic en «Cancelar suscripción». Así de sencillo. Después de cancelar tu suscripción, esta permanecerá activa el tiempo restante que hayas pagado. Obtén más información aquí.
¿Cómo descargo los libros?
Por el momento, todos nuestros libros ePub adaptables a dispositivos móviles se pueden descargar a través de la aplicación. La mayor parte de nuestros PDF también se puede descargar y ya estamos trabajando para que el resto también sea descargable. Obtén más información aquí.
¿En qué se diferencian los planes de precios?
Ambos planes te permiten acceder por completo a la biblioteca y a todas las funciones de Perlego. Las únicas diferencias son el precio y el período de suscripción: con el plan anual ahorrarás en torno a un 30 % en comparación con 12 meses de un plan mensual.
¿Qué es Perlego?
Somos un servicio de suscripción de libros de texto en línea que te permite acceder a toda una biblioteca en línea por menos de lo que cuesta un libro al mes. Con más de un millón de libros sobre más de 1000 categorías, ¡tenemos todo lo que necesitas! Obtén más información aquí.
¿Perlego ofrece la función de texto a voz?
Busca el símbolo de lectura en voz alta en tu próximo libro para ver si puedes escucharlo. La herramienta de lectura en voz alta lee el texto en voz alta por ti, resaltando el texto a medida que se lee. Puedes pausarla, acelerarla y ralentizarla. Obtén más información aquí.
¿Es After Piketty un PDF/ePUB en línea?
Sí, puedes acceder a After Piketty de Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, Marshall Steinbaum, Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, Marshall Steinbaum en formato PDF o ePUB, así como a otros libros populares de Volkswirtschaftslehre y Wirtschaftsgeschichte. Tenemos más de un millón de libros disponibles en nuestro catálogo para que explores.

Información

Año
2017
ISBN
9780674978171

[ III ]

DIMENSIONS OF INEQUALITY

TEN

Increasing Capital Income Share and Its Effect on Personal Income Inequality

BRANKO MILANOVIC
We tend to assume that those with high incomes from capital are also those who are the richest overall; that is, that the association between being capital-rich and overall-income-rich is very close. This is implicit in Piketty’s analysis. He argues that as the share of capital in national income rises, interpersonal inequality will also rise. In our first chapter addressing the dimensions of inequality, economist Branko Milanovic asks under what conditions this is likely to be true.
Milanovic imagines three kinds of societies: socialist, where there is an equal per capita distribution of capital assets; classical capitalist, where workers draw their entire income from labor and capitalists derive their entire income from capital; and “new” capitalist, where everyone receives income from both labor and capital. He uses these archetypes to examine what happens to the inequality—as measured by the Gini coefficient of interpersonal income inequality—if Piketty’s α—the share of capital in net income—rises. Unsurprisingly, he finds that the institutional setup matters. The way the rising share of capital income gets transmitted into greater interpersonal inequality varies between different social systems as a function of the underlying asset distribution. In new capitalism, a rising share of capital income almost directly translates into a higher Gini, while in classical capitalism, this is true once the share of capitalists becomes sufficiently high. In a socialist world, however, a rising capital share does not imply rising interpersonal Gini.

Methodological Contributions of Piketty’s Capital

When discussing Capital in the Twenty-First Century, we need to distinguish between its analytics and methodology, its recommendations, and its forecasts. One can agree with the analytics without agreeing with the recommendations, or the reverse. The methodology introduced by Capital—because it seems to fit quite well the likely evolution of the rich world in the decades to come, and more importantly because it provides a novel way to look at economic phenomena—is probably the most significant contribution of the book. It will affect not only how we think of income distribution and capitalism in the future but also how we think about economic history, from ancient Rome to prerevolutionary France.
The most important methodological contribution of Piketty’s book is his attempt to unify the fields of economic growth, functional income distribution, and personal income distribution.1 In the standard Walrasian system, the three are formally related—but in actual work in economics they were generally treated separately, or some were even simply left out. Functional income distribution was studied much more by Marxist economists. Neoclassical economists tended to assume that capital and labor shares were broadly fixed. This view changed only fairly recently, and we are now witnessing an upsurge of interest in the topic.2 Piketty’s emphasis on the rising share of capital income contributed to this efflorescence.
Personal income distribution tended to be studied almost as divorced from the rest of economics, because in a Walrasian world, agents come to the market with the already-given endowments of capital and labor. Because the original distribution of these endowments is not the subject of economics (narrowly defined), personal income distribution was assumed to be whatever the market generates. But in Capital, the movements in the capital / income ratio—driven by “the fundamental inequality” or “central contradiction of capitalism,” namely r > g (return on capital greater than the growth rate of overall income)—lead to the rising share of capital income in net product. This, in turn, leads to a greater interpersonal inequality.
This chapter concentrates on the last point, which is usually implicitly taken for granted: A greater share of capital is associated, it is thought almost implicitly, with a rising interpersonal inequality. This view is understandable because during most of economic history, people with high capital income were also people with high overall income. Therefore, a greater share of net product going to capitalists came to be associated with greater interpersonal inequality.
In a recent paper investigating the association between higher capital shares and income inequality over the long run (going back in some cases to the mid-nineteenth century), Erik Bengtsson and Daniel Waldenström find, in a country fixed-effect setting, that the correlation has typically been positive and fairly strong. For the entire sample of fifteen advanced economies, they find that, on average, each percentage-point increase in the capital share was associated with a 0.89-point increase in the (log of) top 1 percent income share. When other controls are introduced, the size of the coefficient is reduced, but it remains positive and statistically significant.3 Margaret Jacobson and Filippo Occhino similarly find that for the United States, a 1 percent increase in the capital share tended to increase Gini by between 0.15 percent and 0.33 percent.4
Maura Francese and Carlos Mulas-Granados use more recent 1970s–2010 Luxembourg Income Study microdata from forty-three countries, and decompose the overall change in disposable income Gini into its accounting components: concentration coefficients of labor and capital, labor and capital shares, and changes in taxation and social transfers.5 Unlike Bengtsson and Waldenström, they find a negligible impact of higher capital share, and conclude that most of the increase in disposable income Gini was driven by the rising concentration of wages. They complement the decomposition analysis by a regression on a sample of ninety-three countries, for the 1970s—2013 period, of capital (labor) share on Gini. Once controls are introduced, labor (capital) share is insignificant.6
So the link between greater capital share and increased interpersonal inequality is not as simple and unambiguous as it seems. Even when there exists a positive relationship between the two, the strength of that relationship varies.
The chapter is organized as follows. In the next section I discuss in general the link between the rising share of capital in net income (Piketty’s α) and the Gini coefficient of interpersonal income inequality. Next I look at this relationship in three ideal-typical societies: socialist, classical capitalist, and “new” capitalist....

Índice