The Neomercantilists
eBook - ePub

The Neomercantilists

A Global Intellectual History

Eric Helleiner

Condividi libro
  1. 402 pagine
  2. English
  3. ePUB (disponibile sull'app)
  4. Disponibile su iOS e Android
eBook - ePub

The Neomercantilists

A Global Intellectual History

Eric Helleiner

Dettagli del libro
Anteprima del libro
Indice dei contenuti
Citazioni

Informazioni sul libro

At a time when critiques of free trade policies are gaining currency, The Neomercantilists helps make sense of the protectionist turn, providing the first intellectual history of the genealogy of neomercantilism. Eric Helleiner identifies many pioneers of this ideology between the late eighteenth and early twentieth centuries who backed strategic protectionism and other forms of government economic activism to promote state wealth and power. They included not just the famous Friedrich List, but also numerous lesser-known thinkers, many of whom came from outside of the West.

Helleiner's novel emphasis on neomercantilism's diverse origins challenges traditional Western-centric understandings of its history. It illuminates neglected local intellectual traditions and international flows of ideas that gave rise to distinctive varieties of the ideology around the globe, including in Latin America, the Caribbean, Africa, and Asia. This rich history left enduring intellectual legacies, including in the two dominant powers of the contemporary world economy: China and the United States.

The result is an exceptional study of a set of profoundly influential economic ideas. While rooted in the past, it sheds light on the present moment. The Neomercantilists shows how we might construct more global approaches to the study of international political economy and intellectual history, devoting attention to thinkers from across the world, and to the cross-border circulation of thought.

Domande frequenti

Come faccio ad annullare l'abbonamento?
È semplicissimo: basta accedere alla sezione Account nelle Impostazioni e cliccare su "Annulla abbonamento". Dopo la cancellazione, l'abbonamento rimarrà attivo per il periodo rimanente già pagato. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui
È possibile scaricare libri? Se sì, come?
Al momento è possibile scaricare tramite l'app tutti i nostri libri ePub mobile-friendly. Anche la maggior parte dei nostri PDF è scaricabile e stiamo lavorando per rendere disponibile quanto prima il download di tutti gli altri file. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui
Che differenza c'è tra i piani?
Entrambi i piani ti danno accesso illimitato alla libreria e a tutte le funzionalità di Perlego. Le uniche differenze sono il prezzo e il periodo di abbonamento: con il piano annuale risparmierai circa il 30% rispetto a 12 rate con quello mensile.
Cos'è Perlego?
Perlego è un servizio di abbonamento a testi accademici, che ti permette di accedere a un'intera libreria online a un prezzo inferiore rispetto a quello che pagheresti per acquistare un singolo libro al mese. Con oltre 1 milione di testi suddivisi in più di 1.000 categorie, troverai sicuramente ciò che fa per te! Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui.
Perlego supporta la sintesi vocale?
Cerca l'icona Sintesi vocale nel prossimo libro che leggerai per verificare se è possibile riprodurre l'audio. Questo strumento permette di leggere il testo a voce alta, evidenziandolo man mano che la lettura procede. Puoi aumentare o diminuire la velocità della sintesi vocale, oppure sospendere la riproduzione. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui.
The Neomercantilists è disponibile online in formato PDF/ePub?
Sì, puoi accedere a The Neomercantilists di Eric Helleiner in formato PDF e/o ePub, così come ad altri libri molto apprezzati nelle sezioni relative a Politique et relations internationales e Échanges et tarifs douaniers. Scopri oltre 1 milione di libri disponibili nel nostro catalogo.
Part I

THE LISTIAN INTELLECTUAL WORLD

1

SOME PIONEERS IN LIST’S GERMAN-US-FRENCH CONTEXT

This book encourages readers to see the history of neomercantilist thought in a less List-centric way. It might seem odd, then, that the book begins with a section of four chapters focused on what I have called the Listian intellectual world. As I note in the introductory chapter, however, List’s ideas are important to any history of the emergence of neomercantilist thought. Readers need an understanding of them and this section serves that purpose. But it also begins to develop my case for a wider history in two ways. First, it highlights how some thinkers inspired by List went beyond his ideas in ways that made important contributions to neomercantilist thought. Second, it shows how List himself built on the ideas of a number of earlier neomercantilists.
This chapter examines the ideas of these earlier neomercantilists, while largely leaving the question of how List’s work was influenced by them until the next chapter.1 These thinkers came from three places in which List lived for extended periods of time: the German-speaking world (where he was born in 1789 and lived until 1822 as well as during 1831–37 and 1840–46), the United States (where he resided during 1825–30), and France (where he lived briefly in the early 1820s, 1830–31, and 1837–40).2 Their ideas provide the first examples in this book of important contributions to neomercantilist thought beyond List. They also offer some initial evidence that there were many varieties of this ideology beyond List’s version, that the international circulation of neomercantilist thought involved more than List’s ideas, and that neomercantilist thought built on wider mercantilist traditions than those cited by List.

Hamilton’s Tentative Neomercantilism

Of the thinkers discussed in this chapter, the best known among modern IPE scholars is US politician Alexander Hamilton. Indeed, some IPE textbooks identify Hamilton’s 1791 Report on Manufactures as a pioneering neomercantilist work alongside List’s 1841 book.3 In one sense, this reputation is deserved, because Hamilton was the first prominent thinker to challenge Adam Smith’s ideas on trade policy from a sophisticated neomercantilist perspective. At the same time, it is important to recognize that Hamilton’s endorsement of strategic protectionism was much more lukewarm than that of List and many other early neomercantilists.
Hamilton came to the topic of trade policy with considerable commercial experience. Born on the Caribbean island of St. Croix, he began working for a trading company in the Caribbean region as a young teenager. In 1772, he moved to the United States to pursue education before joining the revolutionary war three years later. After rising quickly to become an aide-de-camp to George Washington, he then went on to become one of the country’s founding fathers, author of a majority of the Federalist Papers, and first treasury secretary of the United States. It was in this latter capacity that he wrote his 1791 report.
Although the report was a policy document responding to a Congressional request, it contained detailed theoretical engagement with Smith’s The Wealth of Nations, which had quickly become widely known in the United States after its publication. Hamilton was particularly interested in the Scottish thinker’s advice that an independent United States should continue to focus its economy on agriculture and resist protective measures designed to build up local manufacturing. Although acknowledging Smith’s logic, Hamilton argued that it still made sense for the government to take an active role in promoting manufacturing “in certain cases, and under certain reasonable limitations.”4
The reasons outlined by Hamilton anticipated many of the arguments that List and other later neomercantilists would make. To begin with, Hamilton argued that local manufacturing was needed to bolster the “independence and security” of the new country. As he put it, “Every nation, with a view to those great objects, ought to endeavour to possess within itself all the essentials of national supply. These comprise the means of Subsistence, habitation, clothing, and defence.” Hamilton highlighted how the experience of his country’s revolutionary war had brought this point home; the “extreme embarrassments of the United States during the late War, from an incapacity of supplying themselves, are still matter of keen recollection.”5 Indeed, Hamilton’s views on this subject were widely shared, including by his mentor Washington, who had argued in his first state of the union address to Congress in 1790 that a “free people . . . should promote such manufacturies as tend to render them independent of others, for essential, particularly military, supplies.”6
Hamilton’s emphasis on the need to protect US sovereignty reflected his concern about the conflictual nature of international relations as well as his skepticism of liberal arguments that the expansion of international commerce would lead to a more peaceful world. In other writing a few years earlier he argued, “Men are ambitious, vindictive, and rapacious,” and asked, “Has commerce hitherto done anything more than change the objects of war?”7 Although Hamilton considered political economy questions from a nationalist perspective rather than a broader cosmopolitan one, his 1791 report did not discuss the relevance of nationality to his economic thought in the detailed way that List would later do.8
In addition to arguments about bolstering his country’s sovereignty, Hamilton outlined many economic reasons for the active government promotion of manufacturing. Some of these related to economic benefits arising from reduced reliance on foreign markets. For example, Hamilton noted that the growth of domestic manufacturing would provide farmers with new local markets, including ones that allowed them to diversify beyond a focus on export crops. He also suggested that demand from these local markets would be steadier for farmers than foreign demand, which was often adversely affected by conditions of foreign harvests or obstacles to international trade. The country’s wealth as a whole would also be boosted by lower transportation costs, as more agricultural products were sold locally and more manufactured goods were purchased from domestic suppliers.
Hamilton highlighted other economic benefits that would stem from a more diversified domestic economy. The greater domestic division of labor would allow an increase in “productive powers of labour, and with them, the total mass of the produce or revenue of a Country.” Hamilton also noted that manufacturing would boost “the total mass of useful and productive labour” in the country by providing new employment opportunities for various groups, including farmers who were not fully occupied all the time and those “who would otherwise be idle (and in many cases a burden on the community) either from the bias of temper, habit, infirmity of body, or some other cause, indisposing or disqualifying them for the toils of the Country.” In the latter category, he added, “it is worthy of particular remark, that, in general, women and Children are rendered more useful, and the latter more early useful by manufacturing establishments, than they would otherwise be.” Hamilton argued that the greater diversity of employment opportunities would furnish “greater scope for the diversity of talents and dispositions which discriminate men from each other.” A more diverse economy would also expand “the spirit of enterprise,” enable domestic businesses to increase exports, attract more foreign customers to local markets, and cope better with sudden drops in demand in specific sectors.9
Hamilton also pointed to some inherent economic benefits of manufacturing production. Citing the invention of the cotton mill in England two decades earlier, he noted “the advantages accruing from the employment of Machinery” in manufacturing in terms of boosting productivity. Hamilton argued that “manufactures open a wider field to exertions of ingenuity than agriculture” and that labor in this sector was more “constant and regular, extending through the year, embracing in some instances night as well as day.” More generally, he suggested that countries reliant on just agricultural exports were subject to disadvantageous terms of trade vis-à-vis manufacturing countries because of the greater “unsteadiness” of foreign demand for their exports.10
If these various benefits would stem from the growth of manufacturing, why did Hamilton think its cultivation required active government measures? One reason was that locals might be discouraged from setting up manufacturing on their own by “the strong influence of habit and the spirit of imitation” or “the fear of want of success in untried enterprises.” A second reason concerned the “intrinsic difficulties” experienced by a new venture that competed with established businesses. Finally, Hamilton noted that foreign governments were supporting their own industries with “bounties premiums, and other aids” in ways that undermined the ability of new US manufacturers to succeed.11
To support the growth of manufacturers, Hamilton highlighted the role that moderate tariffs and targeted bans on imports could play. Although a tariff would raise prices in the short term, he argued that it would lower prices over the longer term, as transportation costs were reduced and local competition increased. Hamilton also noted that trade barriers might encourage a European manufacturer to consider “transfer of himself and his Capital to the United States,” especially if there was the prospect of a growing domestic market to serve. In contrast to some later neomercantilists, Hamilton welcomed this kind of foreign investment: “Instead of being viewed as a rival, it [foreign capital] ought to be Considered as a most valuable auxiliary; conducing to put in Motion a greater Quantity of productive labor, and a greater portion of useful enterprise than could exist without it.”12
At the same time, however, Hamilton thought that there should be sufficient domestic capital to fund local manufacturing, particularly if the financial reforms he proposed to Congress were implemented fully. These reforms included the creation in 1791 of the Bank of the United States, which was to assume central banking functions and act as a commercial bank that could lend to businesses. In justifying this institution, Hamilton highlighted the significance of bank credit to his broad economic goals: “By contributing to enlarge the mass of industrious and commercial enterprise, banks become nurseries of national wealth.”13
His financial reforms also consolidated various official debts accumulated during the revolutionary war into a system of long-term public debt. Hamilton was familiar with the post-1688 English financial revolution, which had encouraged the emergence of that country’s system of funded long-term public debt and the growth of new credit instruments and active secondary markets. Hamilton hoped that his reforms would have the same effect, boosting his country’s wealth and power, including the power to fight wars and to protect itself in a hostile international environment. As he put it, public credit was key to “the strength and security of nations.”14 These various activist financial reforms, in other words, reinforced the core neomercantilist goals of his proposals for promoting domestic manufacturing.
Although Hamilton is known as a critic of free trade, his support of trade protectionism was quite tentative. Protectionist policies should only be used, he argued, if there was enough domestic competition to prevent a monopoly. Hamilton also highlighted the benefits of using temporary government subsidies as an alternative way to encourage manufacturing. This policy would not only avoid causing higher short-term import prices (as well as scarcity and smuggling) but also boost exports in ways that tariffs would not (although Hamilton did not see exports as a leading source of economic growth). More generally, Hamilton noted that...

Indice dei contenuti