Why Progressive Institutions are Unsustainable
eBook - ePub

Why Progressive Institutions are Unsustainable

Richard A. Epstein

Condividi libro
  1. 64 pagine
  2. English
  3. ePUB (disponibile sull'app)
  4. Disponibile su iOS e Android
eBook - ePub

Why Progressive Institutions are Unsustainable

Richard A. Epstein

Dettagli del libro
Anteprima del libro
Indice dei contenuti
Citazioni

Informazioni sul libro

The painful performance of the American economy in the past decade is not a function of bad luck. It is the product of flawed institutional design. Right now we are reaping the harvest of efforts to reinvigorate the progressive programs of the New Deal that stress high progressive taxes, large transfer payments, strong labor laws, and major barriers to free trade.This combination of public finance and market regulation has proved a potent force for disaster.High marginal tax rates expose the political system to strong factional strife that stifles initiative, adds uncertainty and reduces overall revenues. To these multiple ailments, Epstein argues that the best recipe is a return to the flat tax of the classical liberal tradition. The government has committed itself to substituting state mandates for voluntary arrangements in labor and real estate markets, disabling both by retarding job formation and roiling real estate markets. To these multiple ailments, Epstein argues that the best recipe is a reinvigoration of free markets that do not upset voluntary arrangements on the supposed grounds that they are unfair, one-sided or exploitive.Just change these two levers, and we can find an effective classical liberal antidote to excesses of the modern progressive age.

Domande frequenti

Come faccio ad annullare l'abbonamento?
È semplicissimo: basta accedere alla sezione Account nelle Impostazioni e cliccare su "Annulla abbonamento". Dopo la cancellazione, l'abbonamento rimarrà attivo per il periodo rimanente già pagato. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui
È possibile scaricare libri? Se sì, come?
Al momento è possibile scaricare tramite l'app tutti i nostri libri ePub mobile-friendly. Anche la maggior parte dei nostri PDF è scaricabile e stiamo lavorando per rendere disponibile quanto prima il download di tutti gli altri file. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui
Che differenza c'è tra i piani?
Entrambi i piani ti danno accesso illimitato alla libreria e a tutte le funzionalità di Perlego. Le uniche differenze sono il prezzo e il periodo di abbonamento: con il piano annuale risparmierai circa il 30% rispetto a 12 rate con quello mensile.
Cos'è Perlego?
Perlego è un servizio di abbonamento a testi accademici, che ti permette di accedere a un'intera libreria online a un prezzo inferiore rispetto a quello che pagheresti per acquistare un singolo libro al mese. Con oltre 1 milione di testi suddivisi in più di 1.000 categorie, troverai sicuramente ciò che fa per te! Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui.
Perlego supporta la sintesi vocale?
Cerca l'icona Sintesi vocale nel prossimo libro che leggerai per verificare se è possibile riprodurre l'audio. Questo strumento permette di leggere il testo a voce alta, evidenziandolo man mano che la lettura procede. Puoi aumentare o diminuire la velocità della sintesi vocale, oppure sospendere la riproduzione. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui.
Why Progressive Institutions are Unsustainable è disponibile online in formato PDF/ePub?
Sì, puoi accedere a Why Progressive Institutions are Unsustainable di Richard A. Epstein in formato PDF e/o ePub, così come ad altri libri molto apprezzati nelle sezioni relative a Economics e Economic Theory. Scopri oltre 1 milione di libri disponibili nel nostro catalogo.

Informazioni

Anno
2011
ISBN
9781594036279
Argomento
Economics

CLASSICAL LIBERAL VS. MODERN PROGRESSIVE

THE MODERN economic malaise in the United States is captured by two numbers. The first is the decline in average family income, which has slid for the past three years and now stands at the same level, adjusted for inflation, that it was in 1996. The second is the persistent level of unemployment at 9.1 percent, which excludes those who are underemployed or have in frustration given up the search for jobs. Everyone across the political spectrum deplores the result and wishes to reverse the trend. But this unanimity of ends gives way to a fierce difference of opinion on means. Just what should be done?
The deep polarization of views clusters on a broad range of macro- and microeconomic issues. The former covers taxation, deficits, public expenditures. The latter is focused single-mindedly on jobs. The intimate connection between these two is evident from the constant political refrain of whether the priority for government action should lie with the elimination of unemployment or with getting the government’s fiscal house in order. This entire set of problems is complicated further by the precarious position of the real estate markets, as the major decline in real estate values has led to a torrent of underwater residences subject to foreclosures whose frequency increases with the decline in employment levels. The overall landscape is still more clouded because the budgetary position of many states is precarious, to say the least. What should be done about these pressing matters? In dealing with this question, it is hardly productive to revisit the political sniping that takes place on both sides of the aisle. It is far more important to ask about the fundamental differences in approach to ending the admitted stagnation in the economic sphere.
For simplicity, I shall ignore the important issues at the state level and concentrate on the nationwide problems with public finance, unemployment, and housing. It is somewhat hysterical to call the current malaise a depression. The overall levels of material wealth are far higher than they were in 1935, and the toxic brew of high tariffs, major deflation, high marginal tax rates, and incessant cartelization of labor and agricultural markets is less potent today than it was at the height of the New Deal. But to say that today’s economic climate is better than it was at the depths of the depression is not a ringing endorsement of the status quo – nor does it explain what should be done. Matters do not become, nor do they remain, this grim simply by chance. Consistent bad results can only be explained by consistent bad policies and not by some mysterious run of bad luck. Bad policies in turn rest on an unsound worldview. So this nation has reached a crossroads in its choice of first principles. The nation must choose between the oft-rejected classical liberalism of its founding period and the modern progressive stance that served as the foundation of Franklin Delano Roosevelt’s New Deal.
I strongly embrace the former first vision and roundly reject the latter. There is no middle ground on this topic. Nor is there any one way to explain why the progressive vision has led us so badly astray. But it is possible to see what went wrong by focusing on one part of the larger picture: namely, the relative durability of these alternative institutional arrangements. What is needed therefore is a rough measure of the useful half-life of social arrangements. Not even the most ideal set of institutions can just last forever. Every sound set of institutions must be defended, restored, and renewed to undo the damage that political factions of all ideological persuasions seek to turn social events and technological changes to partisan advantages. The problem of factions, both minority and majority, identified by James Madison in “Federalist No. 10,” cannot be wished away by appeals to the virtues of deliberative democracy. What is needed is a choice of robust institutions that do not have to be re-engineered with each technological innovation or social change.
The terms classical liberal and modern progressive may seem quaint to some people, so let me explain why I use them. The former evokes references to 19th century theories of market liberalization, which were intended to reduce the dead hand of government over the operation of the economy. The second recalls the progressive movement of the first third of the 20th century, which championed the rise of the large administrative state to overcome the perceived weaknesses of the classical liberal synthesis. I use that term progressive here for two reasons. First, many Democrats and champions of large government use it as a form of self-identification. Second, their use of the term relocates the center of discussion away from such 1960s issues as criminal procedure, the death penalty, abortion, and affirmative action to the bread-and-butter economic issues dealing with the regulation of financial institutions, home mortgages, labor markets, and health care, all of which hearken back to the New Deal. In defending this modern roster of reforms, moreover, the modern progressives invoke a Keynesian renaissance that places discussions of stimulus packages, multiplier effects, and aggregate demand at the center of the discourse. The classical liberal has the opposite view. Governments are to supply public goods and maintain social stability, leaving innovation to the private sector.
It is somewhat hysterical to call the current malaise a depression.
The key components of the classical liberal theory are as follows. The first component is the call for limited government funded by tax revenues preferably generated under a flat tax (i.e., one that requires uniform rates for the taxable-income individuals, regardless of their aggregate income in any given tax period). In a sound system of public finance, the government’s borrowing to meet the cost of capital improvements is acceptable, but borrowing to pay for short-term-consumption items is not. It is, in other words, proper to use borrowed funds to create long-term capital improvements but not to fund short-term government activity, like the payment of salaries for public employees. Accordingly, the purpose of taxation is to fund the creation of (nonexcludable) public goods that could not be created or maintained without some system of coerced public support. Public finance, however, is no...

Indice dei contenuti