Sovereign Wealth Funds in Resource Economies
eBook - ePub

Sovereign Wealth Funds in Resource Economies

Institutional and Fiscal Foundations

Khalid Alsweilem, Malan Rietveld

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

Sovereign Wealth Funds in Resource Economies

Institutional and Fiscal Foundations

Khalid Alsweilem, Malan Rietveld

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

Sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) have reached a transitional moment. Created as a way to direct excess wealth toward economic development and long-term financial returns, some countries are now seeing a decline in revenue from sources such as oil. Many SWFs are now facing a new challenge—how to spend sustainably without depleting the funds. Sovereign Wealth Funds in Resource Economies explains the fiscal rules and institutional structures that can make SWFs thrive, providing a practical and theoretical guide to their optimal use in resource-revenue management.

Khalid Alsweilem and Malan Rietveld put forward an institutional perspective of SWFs as quasi-independent political and economic entities charged with managing national resource wealth, examining both investment and disbursement strategies. They advance a systematic, rule-based approach, suggesting when to accumulate and when to begin countercyclical spending based on concrete case studies. More than a mere financial portfolio, SWFs must be embedded in a credible fiscal and institutional framework if they are to contribute to improved economic performance. Alsweilem and Rietveld consider the variety of relationships that exist between SWFs and their governments, exploring the legal and policy side of the institutional approach. Their rule-based description of SWFs, since it allows tailoring and adjustment and invokes rules of thumb and best practices, is intended to be widely applicable across the diverse spectrum of global SWFs. Bringing together the practitioner perspective and scholarly expertise, this book will be invaluable for global policy makers and scholars working with sovereign wealth funds.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is Sovereign Wealth Funds in Resource Economies an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access Sovereign Wealth Funds in Resource Economies by Khalid Alsweilem, Malan Rietveld in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Commerce & Industrie de l'extraction des ressources naturelles. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.
PART ONE
An Institutional Perspective on Resource Economies and the Role of Sovereign Wealth Funds
CHAPTER ONE
The Most Disadvantageous Lottery in the World
Historic Controversies Around Natural Resources and Economic Prosperity
The relationship between natural resource wealth and economic prosperity has confounded economists for centuries. At first glance, the idea that an abundance of resources bestow anything other than benefits on their owners is counterintuitive. Natural resources are an essential factor of production, and their scarcity value might therefore be expected to greatly advantage countries and regions in which they are located. These advantages relate both to international trade and fiscal affairs, notably the revenue-generating capacity of resource-rich states. While the existence of a resource curse has gained increasing support in the postwar period, its counterintuitive nature is reflected by associated terms such as the “paradox of plenty” (Karl, 1997).
Scholarship around the resource curse has proliferated in recent decades, but this literature is but the latest in a centuries-old debate in economics that dates back at least as far as the very origins of the discipline. The Physiocrats and mercantilists of the eighteenth century agreed on little, but shared a basic understanding of economic prosperity that was rooted in the accumulation of natural wealth. Adam Smith disagreed. In his view, the wealth of a nation derived from productivity-enhancing specialization with cooperation through markets. He argued that an undue obsession with resources and commodity accumulation undermines the development of a “commercial society,” in which lasting economic prosperity resulted from specialized trade, manufacturing, and the efficient division of labor.
Intellectual traditions do not emerge in a historical vacuum, but are rather embedded in prevailing economic realities. Four major economic epochs signified major shifts in the history of economic thought around resource wealth: the Early Modern Era, the aftermath of the Industrial Revolution, the postwar period in the mid-twentieth century, and the aftermath of the oil shocks in the late 1970s. The latter culminated in the formal articulation of the resource-curse hypothesis. This literature and the vast theoretical and empirical literature that has accompanied its expansion are the focus of this chapter, as they frame and contextualize the central arguments advanced in this book. To underline the deep intellectual origins of the debate, however, we turn first to historical antecedents of the resource curse.
SUCH STRANGE DELUSIONS: HISTORICAL ANTECEDENTS TO THE RESOURCE CURSE
In intellectual traditions that predate the Industrial Revolution, natural wealth was synonymous with agricultural productivity and prowess. Agrarian productivity was regarded as obviously conducive—and indeed tantamount—to economic and social well-being. The Physiocrats, the first Ă©conomistes, who influenced Adam Smith and the emergence of Enlightenment political economy, most famously regarded agricultural prowess as the cornerstone of economic progress. In most other leading philosophies of the Enlightenment, however, natural wealth assumed a wider meaning beyond agriculture.
Mercantilists and the Enlightenment
The moral philosophers of the Scottish Enlightenment, notably David Hume and Adam Smith, held a more qualified view of natural resources in relation to economic wealth than that of the Physiocrats and the bullionist tradition of mercantilism. Indeed, the Scottish Enlightenment political economists’ opposition to the bullionist obsession with rare metals as the measure of wealth was a central criticism of that particular strand of mercantilist logic. While acknowledging the motivational power of the quest for silver and gold to the Iberian colonial expansion during the Age of Discovery, and the extent to which the promise of bountiful raw materials underwrote successive European nations’ expansion into the New World, Smith was deeply critical of the irrationality that accompanied such pursuits.
“The same passion which has suggested to so many people the absurd idea of the philosopher’s stone, has suggested to others the equally absurd one of immense rich mines of gold and silver,” Smith ([1776] 1981:563) argued. Referring to Sir Walter Raleigh’s fixation with the mythical city of El Dorado, Smith argued that so strong was the lure of resource riches, that “even wise men are not always exempt from such strange delusions.” Smith was equally skeptical about the microeconomics of mining. No enterprise was “more perfectly ruinous than the search after new silver and gold mines”—indeed, for Smith, mining constituted “the most disadvantageous lottery in the world [in which] the common price of a ticket is the whole fortune of a very rich man” (Smith [1776] 1981:562).
The most prescient of Smith’s insights on the subject of natural resources, however, pertain to the more general level at which resource wealth creates distractions and incentives that lead economic actors away from more productive endeavors. Smith’s argument in this regard is an early articulation of “rent-seeking,” an argument that has been applied with increasing frequency to the case of resource economies (as discussed in chapter 2). Even when observers understood full well that “the wealth of a country consists, not in its gold and silver only, but in its lands, houses, and consumable goods of all different kinds,” once confronted with resource abundance, “the lands, houses, and consumable goods, seem to slip out of their memory; and the strain of their argument frequently supposes that all wealth consists in gold and silver, and that to multiply those metals is the great object of national industry and commerce” (Smith [1776] 1981:429). Late twentieth-century scholars would observe a similarly slippery grasp of economic beliefs in the face of large resource discoveries.
By the age of the industrial revolutions in Britain, Western Europe, and the United States, the concept of natural wealth shifted toward the direct uses of commodities, such as timber, coal, steel, cotton, copper, and rubber, in industrial processes. Both contemporary observers and subsequent scholarship has identified access to proximate natural resources as an unambiguous boon, and possibility a prerequisite, for economic development and industrialization in that era. The relative ease with which Western European nations accessed supplies of coal, steel, timber, and peat from domestic deposits, as well as peripheral geographies, such as the Baltics and their colonies, has been advanced by some scholars as a—and sometimes the—critical factor in determining why the Industrial Revolution occurred there rather than in other comparatively advanced societies of the period (for a recent articulation of this view, see Pomeranz, 2000; however, the argument dates back to Jevons, 1865).1
Escaping Backwardness: Natural Resources in Postwar Development Economics
The increase in the global trade in commodities in the late nineteenth century reduced the relevance of the geographic proximity to resources that prevailed during the Industrial Revolution. In the United States, trade in agricultural goods and industrial metals increasingly migrated toward formal exchanges, such as the Chicago Board of Trade and the New York Mercantile Exchange, to facilitate more efficient price discovery, risk management (including through the trading of commodity futures and options), and information sharing. Gradually, this mode of trade and market exchange became the norm across agricultural and nonagricultural commodities. On the demand side, rapid economic growth and global trade supported the expansion of commodities trading and production. The inter- and postwar periods of the twentieth century heralded significant growth in the demand for and trade in natural resources, driven by energy- and resource-intensive growth patterns, the rise in automobile usage, and postwar reconstruction efforts. Persistent breakthroughs in transportation (notably, the use of “super tankers,” capable of transporting more than three million barrels of oil) and physical and financial infrastructure further promoted international commodities trading, as well as the globalization of supply and demand dynamics for most natural resources (World Trade Organization, 2010).
Of particular importance to the evolution of the literature on resources and economic development is the emergence during this period of a large number of developing countries as global suppliers of primary products and traded commodities. Consequently, natural resources featured prominently in the grand theories of economic development that emerged after World War II. The emergent field of “development economics” viewed the rapid modernization of poor countries as a distinct challenge and intellectual project, providing a fertile breeding ground for scholarship on the role of natural resources in the economic development of comparatively poor countries.
All the important contributors of this period—Walt Rostow, Albert Hirschman, Hans Singer, Raul Prebisch, Paul Rosenstein-Rodan, Ragnar Nurkse, and Arthur Lewis—addressed the role of the natural resource sector in relation to broader economic development and modernization. While offering contrasting visions of the means and pace through which modernization could be achieved, these theories had in common the belief that the key to economic development lay in moving away from the “backward” economic undertaking of extracting primary goods toward modern industry, characterized by higher skills, productivity, and real wages. Most of these modern development theories—still under the impression of the role of coal, steel, and other industrial resources in the industrialization of Europe and, subsequently, the United States—regarded abundant resources as a catalyst for economic development. Although resource wealth was not viewed as the key to economic prosperity, it was widely regarded as an advantageous starting point.
Rostow’s influential stages-of-growth theory (1960), with its focus on investment and capital accumulation, viewed the extraction of primary goods as the most basic—or, to use his famous term, “backward”—modes of economic production. That said, resource abundance was regarded as critical to mobilizing the requisite savings, investment, and capital formation to advance through predetermined stages of economic development. Indeed, the often large rents and windfalls generated by resource wealth opened up the seductive possibility of “leapfrogging” certain stages of development in Rostow’s view. Arthur Lewis’s similarly influential two-sector model of economic development was built on the assumption that economic development required the release of surplus labor from the primary modes of production and its reallocation toward an urban, capitalist one (Lewis, 1954, 1955). In Lewis’s view, this process would only be accelerated by an abundance of natural resources—indeed, he attempted to show how poor countries could still industrialize even when they were relatively resource poor. Following Rostow, Lewis believed an abundance of natural resources to be a means through which to accelerate an economic transition to modern, industrial capitalism.
A more dirigiste view of how natural resources should advance the goal of rapid economic development and modernization was contained in Rosenstein-Rodan’s (1943) earlier “big push” model, and further expanded on by Nurkse (1961). To achieve “balanced growth,” the big push involved state-directed investments funded by resource windfalls into other sectors of the economy that remained underdeveloped. Rosenstein-Rodan and Nurske argued that in the absence of massive, state-led investment, developing countries would get stuck in a low-equilibrium trap based on specialization in resource production. As with Rostow and Lewis, models in the big push tradition did not regard an abundance of resources as in any way detrimental to the process of modernization, for it merely strengthened the means to achieve balanced growth and modernization, and potentially sped up this process.
Albert Hirschman’s (1958) emphasis on the “forward and backward linkages” between economic activities contained a more qualified view of the role of the resources sector in economic development. In his view, certain primary subsectors, such as agriculture, had relatively few linkages and were therefore not conducive to sustained development, whereas others, such as steel, were characterized by a myriad of such linkages, which could help spur development and growth. It is important to note that Hirschman, who cautioned against heavy-handed state planning and generally favored gradual economic reform and change, opposed Rosenstein-Rodan and Nurske’s “big push” approach. Hirschman was more comfortable with what he reg...

Table of contents