The Curse of Bigness
eBook - ePub

The Curse of Bigness

Antitrust in the New Gilded Age

Tim Wu

Share book
  1. English
  2. ePUB (mobile friendly)
  3. Available on iOS & Android
eBook - ePub

The Curse of Bigness

Antitrust in the New Gilded Age

Tim Wu

Book details
Book preview
Table of contents
Citations

About This Book

"Persuasive and brilliantly written, the book is especially timely given the rise of trillion-dollar tech companies."-- Publishers Weekly From the man who coined the term "net neutrality," author of The Master Switch and The Attention Merchants, comes a warning about the dangers of excessive corporate and industrial concentration for our economic and political future. We live in an age of extreme corporate concentration, in which global industries are controlled by just a few giant firms -- big banks, big pharma, and big tech, just to name a few. But concern over what Louis Brandeis called the "curse of bigness" can no longer remain the province of specialist lawyers and economists, for it has spilled over into policy and politics, even threatening democracy itself. History suggests that tolerance of inequality and failing to control excessive corporate power may prompt the rise of populism, nationalism, extremist politicians, and fascist regimes. In short, as Wu warns, we are in grave danger of repeating the signature errors of the twentieth century.In The Curse of Bigness, Columbia professor Tim Wu tells of how figures like Brandeis and Theodore Roosevelt first confronted the democratic threats posed by the great trusts of the Gilded Age--but the lessons of the Progressive Era were forgotten in the last 40 years. He calls for recovering the lost tenets of the trustbusting age as part of a broader revival of American progressive ideas as we confront the fallout of persistent and extreme economic inequality.

Frequently asked questions

How do I cancel my subscription?
Simply head over to the account section in settings and click on “Cancel Subscription” - it’s as simple as that. After you cancel, your membership will stay active for the remainder of the time you’ve paid for. Learn more here.
Can/how do I download books?
At the moment all of our mobile-responsive ePub books are available to download via the app. Most of our PDFs are also available to download and we're working on making the final remaining ones downloadable now. Learn more here.
What is the difference between the pricing plans?
Both plans give you full access to the library and all of Perlego’s features. The only differences are the price and subscription period: With the annual plan you’ll save around 30% compared to 12 months on the monthly plan.
What is Perlego?
We are an online textbook subscription service, where you can get access to an entire online library for less than the price of a single book per month. With over 1 million books across 1000+ topics, we’ve got you covered! Learn more here.
Do you support text-to-speech?
Look out for the read-aloud symbol on your next book to see if you can listen to it. The read-aloud tool reads text aloud for you, highlighting the text as it is being read. You can pause it, speed it up and slow it down. Learn more here.
Is The Curse of Bigness an online PDF/ePUB?
Yes, you can access The Curse of Bigness by Tim Wu in PDF and/or ePUB format, as well as other popular books in Business & Governance d'impresa. We have over one million books available in our catalogue for you to explore.

Information

Year
2018
ISBN
9780999745472
The Monopolization Movement
From the late nineteenth through the early twentieth century, the United States came under the grip of a powerful political and economic movement whose influence spread across the world and persists today. Known in its time as the Trust Movement, it called for the reorganization of the American and world economy into a new form: the giant, monopoly corporation. It achieved that goal with leviathans like Standard Oil and AT&T in America, I.G. Farben in Germany, and with the domination of the Japanese imperial economy by the zaibatsu system. In its American form, the Trust Movement envisioned an economy with every sector run by a single, almighty monopoly, fashioned out of hundreds of smaller firms, unfettered by competitors or government restraint. In short: pure economic autocracy.
This monopolization movement proceeded with blinding speed in the United States. During just one decade, from 1895 to 1904, at least 2,274 manufacturing firms merged, leaving behind 157 corporations, most of which dominated their industries.* By the early 1900s, nearly every major industry in the United States was either already controlled by, or coming under the control of, a single monopolist. John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil remains the best-known monopoly of the era, but the greater economic impact came from the consolidation campaigns waged by men like banker John Pierpont Morgan, history’s greatest monopolizer. Morgan merged hundreds of steel firms into U.S. Steel, built railroad monopolies in the West and the Northeast, created an Atlantic shipping giant called the International Mercantile Marine Co., and served as the real force behind AT&T’s conquest of the telecommunications industry. His model also inspired other copycat financiers who created a tobacco trust, a cotton trust, a sugar trust, a rubber trust, a filmmakers trust, a trust that made matches, a nail trust, and so on.
To mention Morgan is to summon to mind the top hat, bulbous nose, giant yacht, and access to nearly unlimited capital. His was called the Gilded Age for a reason, for the creation of industry-spanning monopolies was the source of a new kind of wealth that left bankers like Morgan or magnates like Rockefeller with personal fortunes and economic influence previously unknown to the world. To take just one example: To create the U.S. Steel monopoly, and eliminate Andrew Carnegie as a competitor, Morgan agreed to pay him a sum that immediately made Carnegie the richest man in the world, and one of the richest in history. (Carnegie would soon thereafter be worth about $310 billion in current dollars measured by his share of the economy.) But even if the cash payouts of the Trust Movement provided much of the gusto, there was more to it than that. The new monopolists of the Gilded Age preferred to believe that they were not merely profiteering, but building a new and better society. They were bravely constructing a new order that discarded old ways and replaced them with an enlightened future characterized by rule by the strong, by a new kind of industrial Übermensch who transcended humanity’s limitations. The new monopolies were the natural successor to competition, just as man had evolved from the ape.
The Trust Movement’s arguments were, in part, economic: Men like Rockefeller and Morgan simply took the monopoly as a superior form of business organization that was saving the economy from ruin. The U.S. and world economy had undergone terrible shocks in the 1890s, and hundreds of firms were thrown into bankruptcy. Many blamed “ruinous competition” for driving prices too low. In the same way that Silicon Valley’s Peter Thiel today argues that monopoly “drives progress” and that “competition is for losers,” adherents to the Trust Movement thought Adam Smith’s fierce competition had no place in a modern, industrialized economy.
Monopolists liked to portray themselves as part of a progressive movement, striving toward a better age, and justified their work using the then-fashionable ideology of “Social Darwinism” and the writings of its English exponent, Herbert Spencer. Not well known in our times, except, perhaps, as crudely reflected in the writings of novelist Ayn Rand or the monopoly worship of Thiel and other Silicon Valley thinkers, Spencer provided a philosophy for the conquering tycoon, and, for some, even a personal religion.
Here was the faith. Led by the strongest and greatest of men, society was in the midst of an evolutionary transformation, whose goal was nothing less than the forging of a new world order. The weak, the small, and the old-fashioned were all being swept away, to be replaced by the new, the scientific, and above all, the strong. For some, this purge displaced not just old ways and inefficient businesses, but Christianity as well, with its regard for the disadvantaged and insistence on humility before God. Many Social Darwinists believed less in humanity’s sinful nature than man’s perfectibility, personified in the image of a man “looking to the sun,” aspiring to Godlike qualities. The meek were not going to inherit the earth but be eliminated, through the process of a survival of the fittest.
In politics, Social Darwinists embraced laissez-faire, opposing any interventions that might be thought to stop the strong from displacing the weak. Spencer opposed “poor laws” in Britain, believing the impoverished should be left to live or die on their own, so as “to clear the world of them, and make room for better.” To be fair, he and other Social Darwinists did lend support in one form of state intervention: eugenics campaigns meant to cull the physically and mentally disabled, and thereby help speed up the coming of the new age. John D. Rockefeller, Jr., would personally fund an initiative to sterilize some 15 million Americans, for, as Spencer put it, “The forces which are working out the great scheme of perfect happiness… exterminate such sections of mankind as stand in their way, with the same sternness that they exterminate beasts of prey and herds of useless ruminants.”
As between men, so would it be for business. Nothing—certainly not government—should try to stop the great monopolists in their conquest of the economy. For what was underway was a kind of industrial eugenics campaign that exterminated the weak and the unfit to make room for firms great and powerful. John D. Rockefeller, Jr. put it this way: “The American Beauty Rose can be produced in its splendor and fragrance only by sacrificing the early buds which grow up around it.”
Resistance, such as would be waged by Louis Brandeis and his like, was futile, for Morgan’s and Rockefeller’s campaigns were thought to be natural, unstoppable, and perhaps even ordained by God. “To stop co-operation of individuals and aggregation of capital would be to arrest the wheels of progress—to stay the march of civilization—to decree immobility of intellect and degradation of humanity,” explained Standard Oil’s counsel Samuel Dodd, inventor of the Trust form. “You might as well endeavor to stay the formation of the clouds, the falling of the rains, or the flowing of the streams.” Or, as Rockefeller himself put it, “Growth of a large business is merely a survival of the fittest … the working out of a law of nature, and a law of God.”
This was the Trust Movement’s underlying philosophy and vision of what an economy should be: centralized, run by great men, free from any government interference, and to promote survival of the fittest, largely indifferent to the plight or demise of the weak, the poor, and the unfit. It cannot be denied that some of the firms built during this era were impressive creations, and that the American economy, as a whole, experienced impressive if not wholly unprecedented growth. But the monopolization movement also marked a radical break from values once seen as foundational to the Republic, if not the more humanist traditions of Western civilization. As historian Richard Hofstadter put it, “Nothing less was at stake than the entire organization of American business and American politics, the very question of who was to control the country.”
For the American tradition had, to that point, been defined by resistance to centralized power and monopoly. The American Revolution itself was in large part sparked by the abuses of Crown monopolies. The original Boston Tea Party was, after all, really an anti-monopoly protest. As Hofstadter writes: “From its colonial beginnings through most of the nineteenth century, [America] was overwhelmingly a nation of farmers and small-town entrepreneurs—ambitious, mobile, optimistic, speculative, anti-authoritarian, egalitarian, and competitive. As time went on, Americans came to take it for granted that property would be widely diffused, that economic and political power would be decentralized.”
With the assertion that much of economic decision-making was beyond the government’s control, the question of who really ruled the country was suddenly unclear. Fortifying matters was the tendency of great monopolists, like Standard Oil or the New Haven Railroad, to use bribes and other forms of influence to control political outcomes. As such, the movement posed a new challenge for a Constitution that was committed to limited and separate powers, and never contemplated the rise of private power as great as any of the branches of government, and able to corrupt governmental operations to suit its ends.
Perhaps most profound was the break with the ideal that the United States was a nation characterized by a relative sense of equality among its citizens. As Alexis De Tocqueville observed, “Among the novel objects that attracted my attention during my stay in the United States, nothing struck me more forcibly than the general equality of condition among the people.” But that was no longer true for small businesses, farmers, and especially workers. There was a new divide between the giant corporation and its workers, leading to strikes, violence, and a constant threat of class warfare. Looking back, the difference in incomes was so stark it makes today’s America look like Scandinavia; the wealthy might earn millions a year, while the average worker earned between one and two dollars a day.
In short, while the Trust Movement was powerful, lucrative, and had its true believers, it also engendered great popular resistance that threatened a new revolution. Overseas, socialist, communist, and anarchist forces were gaining strength and would in time overthrow many of Europe’s governments. In the United States, outrage was channeled into organized labor, the farmers’ “Granger movement,” the founding of an Anti-Monopoly Party, and the emergence of populist candidates like William Jennings Bryan, three-time Democratic nominee for president.
And it also led to the passage of the first antitrust law, the Sherman Act, enacted in 1890, during the first furious wave of reactions to the rise of the trusts. The law was named after its original sponsor, Senator John Sherman, an Ohio Republican who was the younger brother of the Civil War general William Tecumseh Sherman. While it was clear that the law was meant to address the “Trust Problem,” like many laws, the reasons stated for its passage were many and varied, reflecting a then-recent debate over tariff policy, as well as the interests of small producers, farmers, and others, as modified by the usual dealmaking and compromises. The language of the law is extremely broad. In section one it bans “every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise … in restraint of trade.” In section two it declares that “every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize … any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony.”
The language is so strong—its literal text bans so much—that the scholarly debate over the Sherman Act’s meaning and history may never end. But two things can be stated. It was clearly understood as a reaction to the rising power of the monopoly trusts, such as the Standard Oil Company. And it was evident that the members of Congress had concerns that were diverse and disparate in nature. Consider, for example, the words of Senator Sherman on the floor of the Senate, who discussed the evils of monopoly pricing, but also proclaimed that no problem “is more threatening than the inequality of condition, of wealth, and opportunity” and also added that “if the concerted powers of this combination are entrusted to a single man, it is a kingly prerogative, inconsistent with our form of government.”
Let us not spend any more time on the impossible task of trying to find the true original meaning of the Sherman Act. Instead, we turn to the work of Louis Brandeis, whose philosophy of resistance to the Trust Movement and whose vision of the economy has had an enduring influence, and whose voice is needed for what we confront today.
*Economic historian Naomi Lamoreaux traced the market shares of ninety-three of the major consolidations during that era, and recognized that seventy-two of them were able to gain at least a 40 percent market share in their industry, and forty-two of them gained over 70 percent. The Great Merger Movement in American Business, 1895–1904 (1985).
The Right to Live, and Not Merely to Exist
Louis Brandeis, the advocate, reformer, and Supreme Court Justice, has been done a particular kind of disservice. He is still known as a great jurist; his writings on the First Amendment and privacy are exalted. But what Brandeis really cared about was the economic conditions under which life is lived, and the effects of the economy on one’s character and on the nation’s soul.
This book aspires to resurrect and try to renovate the lost tenets of the Brandeisian economic vision. It envisions a vigorous, healthy economy, a skepticism of the self-serving rhetoric projecting the romance of big business or the inevitability of monopoly, and, above all, a sensitivity to human ends. Brandeis took matters like bigness and concentration as inseparable from the very nature of democracy, and the conditions under which its citizens would live. They determined what kind of country we would live in and what kind of environment that country would provide for its citizens.
Image
Louis Brandeis was born in 1856, in the mid-sized town of Louisville, Kentucky, the son of entrepreneurial immigrants. As is probably true of most of us but is easier to see in Brandeis, these early years would have an important influence over what he thought an economy should ideally look like in a democracy.
His father, Adolph, was born in Prague, to a middle-class family. Adolph decided to take his chances in the Midwest at what was then the American frontier. He was not a particularly good farmer, but found greater success as a grain merchant in Kentucky, and grew to be a prosperous small-business owner. Brandeis’s mother Frederika, the daughter of a Polish court physician, was a devotee of eighteenth-century German authors like Friedrich Schiller and Johann Wolfgang von Goethe, and a moralist who pushed her children to develop “a pure spirit and the highest ideals as to morals and love.”
The town of Louisville would figure essentially in what Brandeis would come to stand for. Louisville was no world capital, nor the seat of any corporate empire, but nonetheless a flourishing regional center, in a United States far more economically decentralized than today’s. It was, economically speaking, dominated by no few large concerns but a multitude of small producers. While the state still suffered the curse of agricultural slavery, Louisville was, at least to Brandeis, an “idyllic” place, one free from the “curse of bigness,” representing an “economic democracy”—that is, a place of industrial freedom and openness to competition, yet with an economy that yielded adequate spoils for all. “Louisville [during his youth]” writes Brandeis biographer Melvin Urofsky, “seemed the quintessential democratic society, in which individuals, like his father … could do well by dint of their intelligence and perseverance. There were no large factories employing thousands of people, but rather many small endeavors—farms, stores, professional offices. People knew one another, their lives entwined in a strong sense of community.”
After high school, Brandeis studied in Germany, achieved famously high grades at Harvard Law School, and developed a passion for canoeing and horseback riding. He decided to make his career in Boston, built a distinguished legal practice, and might have otherwise lived a completely uneventful life had he not been stirred into politics and action by his outrage to that which was happening around him. For in the 1890s, by the time he reached his forties, the Trust Movement had begun its full march on the American economy, acquiring and demolishing smaller businesses and independents right and left. Many of Brandeis’s clients were small-business owners with whom he had a personal relationship. They became the targets of the economic eugenics movement, seen as too unfit to deserve industrial life. In his resistance to the Trust Movement, which at times he seemed to compare to a pogrom, Brandeis gained his identity and formulated the principles of economic decentralization that are now his legacy.
Brandeis’s views crystalized during a battle with a tributary of the Morgan empire. Among Morgan’s many projects was the consolidation of the Northeastern rail and ferry transportation into one monopoly—the New Haven Railroad. Morgan and his anointed lieutenant, Charles Mellen, sought to combine some 336 firms, including Boston’s local railroad, the Boston and Maine, to forge a new system. Brandeis would become the monopolization campaign’s leading public opponent.
Brandeis, who was a business lawyer by trade, and did insurance work in his earlier years, was hardly unsympathetic to the role business played in society. He was happy to praise ...

Table of contents