Money
eBook - ePub

Money

Geoffrey Ingham

Buch teilen
  1. English
  2. ePUB (handyfreundlich)
  3. Über iOS und Android verfĂŒgbar
eBook - ePub

Money

Geoffrey Ingham

Angaben zum Buch
Buchvorschau
Inhaltsverzeichnis
Quellenangaben

Über dieses Buch

Few economic phenomena provoke as much confusion as money. From the first measures of value and the physical coins that circulated at the dawn human civilization to the era of 'virtual' money transmitted through cyberspace, it is ubiquitous and hugely important, yet economists cannot even agree on what it is. In this pithy, accessible book, Geoffrey Ingham cuts through this tangled web of debate to bring rare clarity. Ingham begins by examining the fundamental debate over the nature of money: is it fundamentally a natural, 'neutral' measure of pre-existing value produced by 'real' economic forces? Or is it a socially produced and politically manipulated force that creates new value? He proceeds to trace the import of these competing views for how we understand our contemporary monetary systems and their practical and policy-related implications, from their role in financial crises to proposals for reform. Students of political economy, economic sociology and monetary economics will find this book an invaluable primer, as will general readers wishing to understand how money shapes their lives, from the cash in their pocket to the numbers on their computer screen.

HĂ€ufig gestellte Fragen

Wie kann ich mein Abo kĂŒndigen?
Gehe einfach zum Kontobereich in den Einstellungen und klicke auf „Abo kĂŒndigen“ – ganz einfach. Nachdem du gekĂŒndigt hast, bleibt deine Mitgliedschaft fĂŒr den verbleibenden Abozeitraum, den du bereits bezahlt hast, aktiv. Mehr Informationen hier.
(Wie) Kann ich BĂŒcher herunterladen?
Derzeit stehen all unsere auf MobilgerĂ€te reagierenden ePub-BĂŒcher zum Download ĂŒber die App zur VerfĂŒgung. Die meisten unserer PDFs stehen ebenfalls zum Download bereit; wir arbeiten daran, auch die ĂŒbrigen PDFs zum Download anzubieten, bei denen dies aktuell noch nicht möglich ist. Weitere Informationen hier.
Welcher Unterschied besteht bei den Preisen zwischen den AboplÀnen?
Mit beiden AboplÀnen erhÀltst du vollen Zugang zur Bibliothek und allen Funktionen von Perlego. Die einzigen Unterschiede bestehen im Preis und dem Abozeitraum: Mit dem Jahresabo sparst du auf 12 Monate gerechnet im Vergleich zum Monatsabo rund 30 %.
Was ist Perlego?
Wir sind ein Online-Abodienst fĂŒr LehrbĂŒcher, bei dem du fĂŒr weniger als den Preis eines einzelnen Buches pro Monat Zugang zu einer ganzen Online-Bibliothek erhĂ€ltst. Mit ĂŒber 1 Million BĂŒchern zu ĂŒber 1.000 verschiedenen Themen haben wir bestimmt alles, was du brauchst! Weitere Informationen hier.
UnterstĂŒtzt Perlego Text-zu-Sprache?
Achte auf das Symbol zum Vorlesen in deinem nÀchsten Buch, um zu sehen, ob du es dir auch anhören kannst. Bei diesem Tool wird dir Text laut vorgelesen, wobei der Text beim Vorlesen auch grafisch hervorgehoben wird. Du kannst das Vorlesen jederzeit anhalten, beschleunigen und verlangsamen. Weitere Informationen hier.
Ist Money als Online-PDF/ePub verfĂŒgbar?
Ja, du hast Zugang zu Money von Geoffrey Ingham im PDF- und/oder ePub-Format sowie zu anderen beliebten BĂŒchern aus Economia & Politica economica. Aus unserem Katalog stehen dir ĂŒber 1 Million BĂŒcher zur VerfĂŒgung.

Information

Verlag
Polity
Jahr
2020
ISBN
9781509526857

PART I
WHAT IS MONEY?

1
Money’s Puzzles

The modern world without money is unimaginable. Most probably originating with literacy and numeracy, it is one of our most vital ‘social technologies’ (Ingham, 2004). Obviously, money is essential for the vast number of increasingly global economic transactions that take place; but it is much more than the economists’ medium of exchange. Money is the link between the present and possible futures. A confident expectation that next week’s money will be the same as today’s allows us to map and secure society’s myriad social, economic, and political linkages, including our individual positions, plotted by income, taxes, debts, insurance, pensions, and so on. Without money to record, facilitate, and plan, it would be impossible to create and maintain large-scale societies. In Felix Martin’s apt analogy, money is the modern world’s ‘operating system’ (Martin, 2013).
However, despite money’s pivotal role in modern life, it is notoriously puzzling and the subject of unresolved – often rancorous – intellectual and political disputes that can be traced at least as far back as Aristotle and Plato in Classical Greece and the third century BCE in China (von Glahn, 1996). Many of the innumerable tracts and treatises on money begin with lists of quotations to illustrate people’s bewilderment (see the fine selection in Kevin Jackson’s The Oxford Book of Money [Jackson, 1995]). With characteristic whimsy, the great economist John Maynard Keynes (who knew a great deal about money) said that he was aware of only three people who understood it: one of his students; a professor at a foreign university; and a junior clerk at the Bank of England. The banker Baron Rothschild had made a similar observation a century earlier (quoted in Ingham, 2005, xi), adding that all three disagreed!
We shall see that one of the most puzzling and counterintuitive conceptions of money lies at the core of mainstream economics. We experience money as a powerful force; it ‘makes the world go around’ – and sometimes almost ‘stop’. Governments stand in awe of monetary instability, constantly monitoring rates of inflation and foreign exchange, and levels of state and personal debt. Central banks strive to assure us that they can deliver ‘sound money’ and stability; but – like their predecessors – they are constantly thwarted. Paradoxically, however, from the standpoint of mainstream economic theory, money is not very important. In mathematical models of the economy, money is a ‘neutral’, or passive, element – a ‘constant’ not a ‘variable’. Money is not an active force; it does no more than facilitate the process of production and exchange. Here, the sources of economic value are the ‘real’ factors of production: raw material, energy, labour, and especially technology; money does no more than measure these values and enable their exchange. This conception, which can be traced to Aristotle, had become the established orthodoxy by the eighteenth century. David Hume could confidently declare in his tract ‘Of Money’ (1752) that ‘it is none of the wheels of trade. It is the oil which renders the motion of the wheels more smooth and easy’ (quoted in Jackson, 1995, 3). A little later, in The Wealth of Nations (1776), Adam Smith consolidated the place of ‘neutral money’ in what became known as ‘classical economics’.
Joseph Schumpeter’s mid-twentieth-century identification of the differences between ‘real’ and ‘monetary’ analysis and his summary of the latter’s assumptions has never been bettered:
Real analysis proceeds from the principle that all essential phenomena of economic life are capable of being described in terms of goods and services, of decisions about them, and of relations between them. Money enters into the picture only in the modest role of a technical device 
 in order to facilitate transactions
. [S]o long as it functions normally, it does not affect the economic process, which behaves in the same way as it would in a barter economy: this is essentially what the concept of Neutral Money implies. Thus, money has been called a ‘garb’ or ‘veil’ over the things that really matter
. Not only can it be discarded whenever we are analyzing the fundamental features of the economic process but it must be discarded just as a veil must be drawn aside if we are to see the face behind it. Accordingly, money prices must give way to the ratios between the commodities that are the really important thing ‘behind’ money prices. (Schumpeter 1994 [1954], 277, original emphasis)
This view remains at the core of modern mainstream macroeconomics, which argues that money does not influence ‘real’ factors in the long run: that is, productive forces – especially advances in material technology – are ultimately the source of economic value. Therefore, ‘[f]or many purposes 
 monetary neutrality is approximately correct’ (Mankiw and Taylor, 2008, 126, which is a representative text). However, there is an alternative view: ‘monetary analysis’ follows a view of money which prevailed in the practical world of business before the classical economists’ theoretical intervention (Hodgson, 2015). Here money is money-capital – a dynamic independent economic force. Money is not merely Hume’s ‘oil’ for economic ‘wheels’; it is, rather, the ‘social technology’ without which the ‘classical’ economists’ physical capital cannot be set in motion and developed. This distinction, between ‘real’ analysis and ‘monetary’ analysis, is known as the ‘Classical Dichotomy’.
Money itself cannot create value; but in capitalism the wheels are not set in motion and production is not consumed without the necessary prior creation of money for investment, production, and consumption (see Smithin, 1918). In the ‘classical’ view, the ‘real’ economy is in fact an ‘unreal’ model of a pure exchange, or market, economy in which money is the medium for the exchange of commodities: that is, Commodity–Money–Commodity (C–M–C). Here, money enables individuals to gain utility: that is, satisfaction from the commodity. In ‘real-world’ capitalism, money is the goal of production – the realization of money-profit from the employment of money-capital and wage-labour: that is, Money (capital)–Commodity–Money (profit) (M–C–M). As Marx and Keynes stressed, depressions and unemployment are not caused by the failure of ‘real’ productive forces. These can lie idle for want of money for investment and consumption not only in the immediate short term but also in the long run. And as Keynes scathingly remarked, the ‘long run is a misleading guide to current affairs. In the long run we are all dead. Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if in tempestuous seasons they can only tell us that when the storm is long past the ocean is flat again’ (Keynes, 1971 [1923], 65, original emphasis).
For economic orthodoxy, the proponents of monetary analysis were ‘cranks’ who were banished to an academic and intellectual ‘underground’ (Keynes, 1973 [1936], 3, 32, 355; Goodhart, 2009). But, for Keynes, they were ‘brave heretics’ whose analysis was revived and greatly elaborated in his The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (1936). A late nineteenth-century American ‘crank’, Alexander Del Mar – unknown to Keynes – has only recently come to light (Zarlenga, 2002). He anticipated Keynes’s general position on monetary theory and policy:
Money is a Measure 
 the Unit of money is All Money within a given legal jurisdiction
. The wheels of Industry are at this moment clogged, and what clogs them is that materialistic conception which mistakes a piece of metal for the measure of an ideal relation, a measure that resides not at all in the metal, but in the numerical relation of the piece to the set of pieces to which it is legally related, whether of metal, or paper, or both combined. (Del Mar, 1901, 8)
Keynes sought theoretically to convince his ‘classical’ orthodox mentors and colleagues that government expenditure, financed by money created in advance of tax revenue, could solve chronic unemployment in the 1930s. Money created by government spending would increase production and employment, which, in turn, would increase ‘effective aggregate demand’: that is, real ‘purchasing power’. As opposed to the subjective ‘wants’ and ‘preferences’ of orthodox economic theory, demand created by expenditure was both ‘effective’ and ‘aggregate’, inaugurating a positive cycle of growth and tax revenue to fund the original deficit. For a while during and after the Second World War, Keynesian versions of ‘monetary analysis’ gained acceptance in theory and policy. However, as we shall see, the 1970s crises were held to have discredited Keynesian economics, leading to a revival of the old orthodoxy of ‘neutral’ money and the ‘real’ economy.
The two kinds of economic analysis and their respective theories of money lie behind arguably this most contested question in the governance of capitalism. On the one hand, mainstream economics believes that the supply of money may have a short-run positive effect, but cannot and therefore should not exceed the economy’s productive capacity in the long run. Only ‘real’ forces of production – technology, labour – create new value, and their input cannot be increased simply by injections of money. Consequently, if monetary expansion runs ahead of these ‘real’ forces, inflation inevitably follows. On the other hand, the broadly Keynesian and heterodox tradition continues to argue that money is the vital productive resource – a ‘social technology’ – that can be used to create non-inflationary economic growth and employment.
However, it is of the utmost importance that the theoretical dispute is not seen exclusively as an ‘academic’ question; theories of money are also ideological. Our understanding of money’s nature – what it is and how it is produced – is intimately bound up with conflict over who should control its creation and, by implication, how it is used. Insisting that money is nothing more than a ‘neutral’ element in the economy implies that it can be safely removed from politics. If money were merely a passive instrument for measuring pre-existing values of commodities and enabling their exchange, then disputes over its use would be misguided. All we need to do is ensure that there is enough money for it to fulfil its functions and ensure the smooth operation of the economic system – which is precisely how the money question is most frequently posed. The retired Governor of the Bank of England, Mervyn King, wrote in his recent memoirs that “[in essence] 
 the role of a central bank is extremely simple: to ensure that the right amount of money is created in both good and bad times” (King, 2017, xxi). The quantity of money should be calibrated to enable the consumption of what has been produced. Too little money will depress activity as goods cannot be bought; and too much money will do no more than inflate prices.
Here we encounter another of money’s many puzzles. From a theoretical standpoint, it might be a simple matter to supply the right amount of money, but in practice it is not. We shall see that the experiment with ‘monetarist’ policy to control the money supply in the 1980s was beset by two related problems (see chapter 4). Confronted by the complexity of different forms of money in modern capitalism, the monetary authorities were unsure about what should count as money and how it should be counted. Notes and coins – cash – were an insignificant component of the money supply. But which of the other forms of money – bank accounts, deposits – and forms of credit – credit cards and private IOUs used in financial networks – should be included? Furthermore, many of the non-cash forms were beyond the control of the monetary authorities (see chapter 6).
Despite monetary authorities’ many obvious practical and technical problems in conducting ‘monetary policy’ – essentially, attempting to control inflation – the long-run neutrality of money remains a core assumption of most mainstream economics. To believe otherwise – that money can be used as an independent creative force – is to suffer from the ‘money illusion’. As we shall see, the ‘illusion’ is to think that money has powers beyond its function as a simple instrument that only measures existing value and enables economic exchange. However, the centuries-old persistence and intensity of the unresolved disputes tells us that money is not merely this technical device to be managed by economic experts. Rather, it is also a source of social power to get things done (‘infrastructural power’) and to control people (‘despotic power’) (Ingham, 2004, 4). The ‘money question’ lies at the centre of all political struggles about the kind of society we want and how it might be achieved.
In the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, the longstanding intellectual, ideological, and political debates on money became embroiled in an acrimonious academic dispute about the most appropriate methods for the study of society, which ultimately led to the formation of the distinct disciplines of economics and sociology (Ingham, 2004). In 1878, exasperated by the endless wrangling, American economist Francis Amasa Walker decided on a deceptively simple solution (see Schumpeter, 1994 [...

Inhaltsverzeichnis