Commonwealth Caribbean Contract Law
eBook - ePub

Commonwealth Caribbean Contract Law

Gilbert Kodilinye, Maria Kodilinye

Buch teilen
  1. 374 Seiten
  2. English
  3. ePUB (handyfreundlich)
  4. Über iOS und Android verfĂŒgbar
eBook - ePub

Commonwealth Caribbean Contract Law

Gilbert Kodilinye, Maria Kodilinye

Angaben zum Buch
Buchvorschau
Inhaltsverzeichnis
Quellenangaben

Über dieses Buch

The first textbook on Commonwealth Caribbean Contract law for undergraduate and sixth form students, Commonwealth Caribbean Contract Law is a new and unrivalled resource on the subject. This textbook utilises Caribbean Case Law and Statutory provisions to provide a clear and immersive path into the study of contract law from a Caribbean perspective. Encompassing topics that include misrepresentation, privity, and remedies, this book expertly introduces and explains the many aspects of contract law in the Caribbean.

Written by a well-established textbook author and professor of law at Mona Campus, the textbook comprehensively covers all key principles of contractual obligations studied by undergraduate students, and is relevant to practitioners in a modern and accessible way. An invaluable reference, this book is essential reading for those with an academic or professional interest in contract law.

HĂ€ufig gestellte Fragen

Wie kann ich mein Abo kĂŒndigen?
Gehe einfach zum Kontobereich in den Einstellungen und klicke auf „Abo kĂŒndigen“ – ganz einfach. Nachdem du gekĂŒndigt hast, bleibt deine Mitgliedschaft fĂŒr den verbleibenden Abozeitraum, den du bereits bezahlt hast, aktiv. Mehr Informationen hier.
(Wie) Kann ich BĂŒcher herunterladen?
Derzeit stehen all unsere auf MobilgerĂ€te reagierenden ePub-BĂŒcher zum Download ĂŒber die App zur VerfĂŒgung. Die meisten unserer PDFs stehen ebenfalls zum Download bereit; wir arbeiten daran, auch die ĂŒbrigen PDFs zum Download anzubieten, bei denen dies aktuell noch nicht möglich ist. Weitere Informationen hier.
Welcher Unterschied besteht bei den Preisen zwischen den AboplÀnen?
Mit beiden AboplÀnen erhÀltst du vollen Zugang zur Bibliothek und allen Funktionen von Perlego. Die einzigen Unterschiede bestehen im Preis und dem Abozeitraum: Mit dem Jahresabo sparst du auf 12 Monate gerechnet im Vergleich zum Monatsabo rund 30 %.
Was ist Perlego?
Wir sind ein Online-Abodienst fĂŒr LehrbĂŒcher, bei dem du fĂŒr weniger als den Preis eines einzelnen Buches pro Monat Zugang zu einer ganzen Online-Bibliothek erhĂ€ltst. Mit ĂŒber 1 Million BĂŒchern zu ĂŒber 1.000 verschiedenen Themen haben wir bestimmt alles, was du brauchst! Weitere Informationen hier.
UnterstĂŒtzt Perlego Text-zu-Sprache?
Achte auf das Symbol zum Vorlesen in deinem nÀchsten Buch, um zu sehen, ob du es dir auch anhören kannst. Bei diesem Tool wird dir Text laut vorgelesen, wobei der Text beim Vorlesen auch grafisch hervorgehoben wird. Du kannst das Vorlesen jederzeit anhalten, beschleunigen und verlangsamen. Weitere Informationen hier.
Ist Commonwealth Caribbean Contract Law als Online-PDF/ePub verfĂŒgbar?
Ja, du hast Zugang zu Commonwealth Caribbean Contract Law von Gilbert Kodilinye, Maria Kodilinye im PDF- und/oder ePub-Format sowie zu anderen beliebten BĂŒchern aus Diritto & Teoria e pratica del diritto. Aus unserem Katalog stehen dir ĂŒber 1 Million BĂŒcher zur VerfĂŒgung.

Information

Verlag
Routledge
Jahr
2013
ISBN
9781135047542

CHAPTER 1

INTRODUCTION

NATURE AND FUNCTIONS OF CONTRACT LAW

The law of contract may be defined as that branch of the law which determines the circumstances in which a promise will be legally binding on the person making the promise (the ‘promisor’) and enforceable in a court of law by the person to whom the promise was made (the ‘promisee’). A well- accepted definition is that contained in section 1 of the American Law Institute's Second Restatement of the Law of Contracts: ‘A contract is a promise or a set of promises for the breach of which the law gives a remedy, or the performance of which the law in some way recognizes as a duty.’
The rationale for the enforceability of contracts is essentially the promotion of trade and commerce, which would be seriously hampered if contracting parties could not be held to their bargains. Accordingly, a party which enters into a valid contract can be assured that it will be able to recover compensation from the other party in the event of the latter's repudiation of the agreement or failure to perform its obligations, and the ‘measure’ (i.e. the amount) of damages recoverable in contract law is intended to compensate the innocent party not only for any material or financial damage sustained on account of the other party's breach, but also for any loss of profits or other benefits which it would have received if the contract had been performed by that other party.
Enforceable contracts appear in a great variety of forms, ranging from, on the one hand, ‘everyday’ contracts entered into by consumers, such as those for the sale of goods in a supermarket, or for transportation of a passenger in a bus, train or plane, or for professional services to be rendered by a dentist, plumber or hairdresser to, on the other, complex commercial agreements such as large- scale building and civil engineering contracts affecting several corporate parties, any breach of which could inflict serious financial damage on one or more of the parties. An example of such complex relationships in the Caribbean might occur in the context of the construction of a resort complex involving the following parties and transactions:
(a) A property developer purchases a site for building, with money obtained by way of a loan on mortgage from a bank.
(b) The developer appoints an architect to design the buildings, a landscape artist to design the gardens, a quantity surveyor to draw up bills of quantities, and an attorney to do the conveyancing work.
(c) Tenders are invited for the building work, and the contractor whose tender is accepted is appointed as ‘main contractor’ under the contract between him/it and the developer.
(d) The main contractor subcontracts various parts of the building work to specialist subcontractors, thereby creating contractual relations between the main contractor and the subcontractors.
In such a scenario, each of the parties will depend on the others to carry out their contractual obligations and, in the event of a breach by a promisor, the innocent promisee under the particular contract will have a right of action for breach of contract against the defaulting promisor. Thus, for example, an architect who produces defective drawings may be liable to the developer, as will a main contractor who uses materials which do not comply with the specifications for the work, or who fails to complete within the period specified by the contract. Similarly, a subcontractor who is in default may be liable to the main contractor, and a developer will be liable to the main contractor for failure to pay him promptly at the stages provided by the contract. In short, it may be said that ‘contract is, in effect, the instrument by which the separate and conflicting interests of the participants can be reconciled and brought to a common goal’.1

Freedom of contract

The concept of ‘freedom of contract’ became a basic tenet of jurists, philosophers and economists in the nineteenth century, and it persisted in mainstream legal thinking until comparatively recently. At the heart of this principle is the notion that a party to a contract is expected to decide what is in his own best interests, and the law's function is simply to enforce agreements and not to interfere with them on grounds of ‘unfairness’ or ‘unreasonableness’. This is the essence of laissez- faire economics. However, according to some contemporary jurists, the laissez- faire approach is acceptable only where the parties to a contract have ‘equal bargaining power’, which would be the case where a contract is concluded between two corporate entities of equal economic ‘muscle’, but not where an individual consumer enters into a contract with, for instance, a utility company for the supply of electricity or telephone service, where the terms of the contract are standardised and not subject to bargaining, and where the consumer has no alternative but to accept those terms. 2 Accordingly, limited protection for contracting parties having little or no bargaining power is afforded by statutory provisions in many jurisdictions,3 and the courts, in some instances, have refused to enforce contractual exemption clauses imposed by a stronger party on the weaker.4 Nevertheless, in 1967, Lord Reid, commenting on the effect of the so- called ‘doctrine of fundamental breach’,5 deprecated the idea of restricting ‘the general principle of English Law that parties are free to contract as they may think fit’, and in 1980, Lord Diplock reiterated the ‘basic principle of the common law of contract 
 that the parties are free to determine for themselves what primary obligations they will accept’.6

Sanctity of contracts

The principle of sanctity of contracts means that a contract, once made, must be observed and promises must be kept. The principle serves the requirements of the commercial community by giving security and certainty to contractual relations and providing assurance that transactions involving financial commitments on the part of the contracting parties will be enforced by the courts. The strictness of the principle is exemplified by the courts' refusal, before 1863, to allow a party to be freed of his contractual obligations on the ground of frustration. Before the case of Taylor v Caldwel7 it was a strict rule that a party could not escape his obligations under a contract by pleading that a fundamental change in the circumstances since the date of the agreement had ‘frustrated’ the contract. Today, frustration is accepted as a ground for discharging a contract, but the circumstances in which the courts will allow the plea to succeed remain severely limited, and the current position is that frustration will discharge a contract only where the frustrating event ‘strikes at the root of the contract’, so that the agreement, after the event, becomes fundamentally different in character from that originally contemplated by the parties.8

Contract distinguished from tort

Owing to the manner in which tortious and contractual obligations developed simultaneously throughout the history of the common law, the precise relationship between the two areas of law is a matter of debate, and there is a school of thought which argues that tort and contract should be subsumed under a ‘law of civil obligations’.
The traditional distinction made between tort and contract is that, in tort, the duties of the parties are primarily fixed by law, whereas in contract they are fixed by the parties themselves. Put another way, contractual duties arise from agreement between the parties, whereas tortious duties exist by operation of law, independently of the consent of the parties. This distinction may be misleading, however, for, in the first place, although contractual obligations are certainly created by agreement, the parties are nonetheless subjected to the underlying principles of contract law developed by the courts. Second, the duties owed by contracting parties towards one another are frequently not duties which they expressly agreed upon but obligations which the law implies, such as the terms implied under sale of goods and hire purchase legislation.9 Conversely, some duties in tort can be varied by agreement, for example, the duties owed by an occupier of premises to his lawful visitors; and liability in tort can be excluded altogether by consent.
Other points of distinction between contract and tort are:
(a) Damages for purely economic loss are recoverable in contract, whereas such loss is generally not ...

Inhaltsverzeichnis