Rethinking Real Estate
eBook - ePub

Rethinking Real Estate

A Roadmap to Technology's Impact on the World's Largest Asset Class

Dror Poleg

Partager le livre
  1. English
  2. ePUB (adapté aux mobiles)
  3. Disponible sur iOS et Android
eBook - ePub

Rethinking Real Estate

A Roadmap to Technology's Impact on the World's Largest Asset Class

Dror Poleg

DĂ©tails du livre
Aperçu du livre
Table des matiĂšres
Citations

À propos de ce livre

Technology is revolutionizing the way real estate is designed, operated, and valued. It is democratizing access to capital and information, changing the way tenants use space, and eroding the power of regulation. Billions of dollars are funding these new real estate technologies and operating models. Value is shifting away from the assets themselves toward those who understand the needs of specific end-users and can use technology to deliver comprehensive, on-demand solutions. With all of these developments, there is an urgent need for a resource that helps industry practitioners think differently about their investment, customers, and competition.

Rethinking Real Estate answers that call. It explores the impact of technology on all asset types — from retail projects, through lodging and residential properties, to office buildings and industrial facilities. Based on the author's two decades of experience working across four continents alongside the world's leading realestate investors, as well as hundreds of conversations with start-up founders and venture capitalists, this book provides practitioners with key insights, methodologies, and practical strategies to identify risks, take advantage of emerging opportunities, evaluate new competitors, and transform their organization, project, venture, or career.

Whether you are an investor, developer, operator, broker, lender, facility manager, designer, planner, or technology entrepreneur, this book will help you navigate the exciting period ahead.

Foire aux questions

Comment puis-je résilier mon abonnement ?
Il vous suffit de vous rendre dans la section compte dans paramĂštres et de cliquer sur « RĂ©silier l’abonnement ». C’est aussi simple que cela ! Une fois que vous aurez rĂ©siliĂ© votre abonnement, il restera actif pour le reste de la pĂ©riode pour laquelle vous avez payĂ©. DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Puis-je / comment puis-je télécharger des livres ?
Pour le moment, tous nos livres en format ePub adaptĂ©s aux mobiles peuvent ĂȘtre tĂ©lĂ©chargĂ©s via l’application. La plupart de nos PDF sont Ă©galement disponibles en tĂ©lĂ©chargement et les autres seront tĂ©lĂ©chargeables trĂšs prochainement. DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Quelle est la différence entre les formules tarifaires ?
Les deux abonnements vous donnent un accĂšs complet Ă  la bibliothĂšque et Ă  toutes les fonctionnalitĂ©s de Perlego. Les seules diffĂ©rences sont les tarifs ainsi que la pĂ©riode d’abonnement : avec l’abonnement annuel, vous Ă©conomiserez environ 30 % par rapport Ă  12 mois d’abonnement mensuel.
Qu’est-ce que Perlego ?
Nous sommes un service d’abonnement Ă  des ouvrages universitaires en ligne, oĂč vous pouvez accĂ©der Ă  toute une bibliothĂšque pour un prix infĂ©rieur Ă  celui d’un seul livre par mois. Avec plus d’un million de livres sur plus de 1 000 sujets, nous avons ce qu’il vous faut ! DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Prenez-vous en charge la synthÚse vocale ?
Recherchez le symbole Écouter sur votre prochain livre pour voir si vous pouvez l’écouter. L’outil Écouter lit le texte Ă  haute voix pour vous, en surlignant le passage qui est en cours de lecture. Vous pouvez le mettre sur pause, l’accĂ©lĂ©rer ou le ralentir. DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Est-ce que Rethinking Real Estate est un PDF/ePUB en ligne ?
Oui, vous pouvez accĂ©der Ă  Rethinking Real Estate par Dror Poleg en format PDF et/ou ePUB ainsi qu’à d’autres livres populaires dans Business et Real Estate. Nous disposons de plus d’un million d’ouvrages Ă  dĂ©couvrir dans notre catalogue.

Informations

Année
2019
ISBN
9783030134464
Sous-sujet
Real Estate
© The Author(s) 2020
D. PolegRethinking Real Estatehttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-13446-4_1
Begin Abstract

1. Introduction: Real Estate Value in a Changing World

Dror Poleg1
(1)
Rethinking Real Estate, Brooklyn, NY, USA
End Abstract
“I had never seen such ugly cows in all the land of Egypt,” said the Pharaoh. “The lean, ugly cows ate up the seven fat cows that came up first. But even after they ate them 
 they looked just as ugly as before. Then I woke up.”
Joseph listened intently and interpreted the dream as follows: the kingdom’s farmland was about to experience seven years of unprecedented yields, followed by seven years of drought. He told the Pharaoh that “the abundance in the land will not be remembered, because the famine that follows it will be so severe”. In order to prepare, Joseph advised the Pharaoh to “collect all the food of these good years that are coming 
 to be kept in the cities for food”.i
As the biblical story shows, humanity has been preoccupied with real estate yields since time immemorial. Even in ancient Egypt 3500 years ago, young upstarts were trying to guide powerful rulers to adopt more sustainable policies, reinvest their proceeds in new systems, and think strategically. And even the Pharaoh, owner of all the land in Egypt, was subject to disruption by powers that he could not understand or control.
Farmland is the quintessential real estate asset. It is valued based on its inherent characteristics and bears relatively stable and predictable returns. Unlike other real estate assets, it does not require expensive maintenance or complex ventilation or electric systems, and its value cannot be depreciated—at least according to the IRS.ii Farmland is also a scarce commodity and its ownership involves little-to-no interaction with customers.
Many of the words we now use to describe all real estate assets—landlord, yield, tenant, improvements—originate in the agricultural world. Many of the attitudes and assumptions we have toward real estate are equally ancient.

An Asset Like No Other

What makes something valuable? The answer may be clear to any reasonable person, but economists have spent hundreds of years arguing about it. Adam Smith and Karl Marx didn’t agree on much, but they both thought that the value of a thing was a function of the amount of labor required to produce it.
But how much labor goes into producing land? Figuring out the value of property, including the improvements erected on it, is a challenge. Marx struggled with the idea that land “is essential to the production” of everything but “is not itself produced”.iii If land is not “produced”, then its value cannot be equal to the value of labor invested in its production. So why should anyone pay for it?
Smith saw rent as a consequence of landlords’ power and not a result of any unique effort, stating that “the price paid for the use of the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It is not at all proportioned to what the landlord may have laid out upon the improvement of the land, or to what he can afford to take; but to what the farmer can afford to give.”iv
Smith thought that being a landlord was an easy enough job. As he wrote in The Wealth of Nations, landlords’ “revenue costs them neither labour nor care, but comes to them, as it were, of its own accord, and independent of any plan or project”. This, in turn, led landlords to “indolence, which is the natural effect of the ease and security of their situation”. In 1844, Karl Marx quoted Smith’s view of landlords in his Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts.
A century after Smith, and not long after Marx’s death, economics went through a revolution that turned the idea of value on its head. A new group of thinkers arrived at the conclusion that things do not have a fixed, objective value based on the cost of labor that goes into them. Instead, the value of a thing is subjective—and it is the result of the utility it provides to an individual buyer. And because each buyer is different, things are worth more to some people than they are to others.
This means that simply owning something is not enough. To maximize the value of an asset, you have to market it to those who are willing to pay more for it than anyone else. This so-called revolutionary idea makes intuitive sense to any businessperson. Yet, in large part, many still assume that it does not apply to real estate assets, at least not completely.
As Professor Andrew Baum of Oxford University’s Saïd Business School pointed out, unlike other businesses, real assets are valuable even when they do not have customers or generate any income. Landlords are called landlords for a reason: they own land, and land is inherently scarce and is thus inherently valuable.v The assumption of inherent value still drives many real estate owners and operators to the “indolence” highlighted by Adam Smith and Karl Marx.

Real Estate Value 101

What determines the value of a real estate asset? Valuation professionals commonly refer to four characteristics:
  1. 1.
    Demand : The quantity of people or entities who have the desire and ability to pay for the property;
  2. 2.
    Utility : The ability of the property to meet the needs of prospective owners (and their tenants). The broader an asset’s ability to serve different needs, the higher its utility;
  3. 3.
    Scarcity : The available substitutes for the property compared to the intensity of demand for it; and
  4. 4.
    Transferability : The freedom to buy, lease, encumber, or sell the asset at will.
Based on the above, the ideal asset is one that meets the needs of the largest group of people, has limited substitutes, can be transacted freely by its owner, and exists within a reasonably liquid market. You may have noticed that there is a tension between “utility” and “scarcity”: if all landlords try to meet the needs of the largest possible group of people, the result will be an abundance of very similar assets—the opposite of scarcity.
How did real estate owners deal with this tension until now? The short answer is that they mostly didn’t. Real estate assets are special. They are built on land, which makes them inherently scarce and immovable. Land scarcity protects landlords from “substitutes” and frees them to develop assets that appeal to a broad range of end users. In other words, natural constraints allowed and encouraged them develop average assets for average tenants.
But scarcity is a double-edged sword. It makes it difficult for competitors to “move in” on your market (buildings can’t move). And it also makes it impossible for your own asset to move anywhere else. Other scarce resources such as oil and precious metals can be distributed to ideal customers who would pay the highest price. In contrast, real property is both a form of supply and a form of distribution; its ideal customer is whoever happens to need access to that location at that time. Once a real estate company makes a bet on a location, it is locked in.
Lock-in provides an extra incentive for landlords to develop assets that can suit the needs of different tenants in succession. If a building can’t move, it needs to be able to adapt. For example, a typical office space in Midtown Manhattan served a law firm during one decade, a media company during the next, and a financial services firm in the decade after that. In...

Table des matiĂšres