A History of Econometrics in France
eBook - ePub

A History of Econometrics in France

Philippe Le Gall

Partager le livre
  1. 296 pages
  2. English
  3. ePUB (adapté aux mobiles)
  4. Disponible sur iOS et Android
eBook - ePub

A History of Econometrics in France

Philippe Le Gall

DĂ©tails du livre
Aperçu du livre
Table des matiĂšres
Citations

À propos de ce livre

This text challenges the traditional view of the history of econometrics and provides a more complete story. In doing so, the book sheds light on the hitherto under-researched contribution of French thinkers to econometrics. Fascinating and authoritative, it is a comprehensive overview of what went on to be one of the defining subsets within t

Foire aux questions

Comment puis-je résilier mon abonnement ?
Il vous suffit de vous rendre dans la section compte dans paramĂštres et de cliquer sur « RĂ©silier l’abonnement ». C’est aussi simple que cela ! Une fois que vous aurez rĂ©siliĂ© votre abonnement, il restera actif pour le reste de la pĂ©riode pour laquelle vous avez payĂ©. DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Puis-je / comment puis-je télécharger des livres ?
Pour le moment, tous nos livres en format ePub adaptĂ©s aux mobiles peuvent ĂȘtre tĂ©lĂ©chargĂ©s via l’application. La plupart de nos PDF sont Ă©galement disponibles en tĂ©lĂ©chargement et les autres seront tĂ©lĂ©chargeables trĂšs prochainement. DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Quelle est la différence entre les formules tarifaires ?
Les deux abonnements vous donnent un accĂšs complet Ă  la bibliothĂšque et Ă  toutes les fonctionnalitĂ©s de Perlego. Les seules diffĂ©rences sont les tarifs ainsi que la pĂ©riode d’abonnement : avec l’abonnement annuel, vous Ă©conomiserez environ 30 % par rapport Ă  12 mois d’abonnement mensuel.
Qu’est-ce que Perlego ?
Nous sommes un service d’abonnement Ă  des ouvrages universitaires en ligne, oĂč vous pouvez accĂ©der Ă  toute une bibliothĂšque pour un prix infĂ©rieur Ă  celui d’un seul livre par mois. Avec plus d’un million de livres sur plus de 1 000 sujets, nous avons ce qu’il vous faut ! DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Prenez-vous en charge la synthÚse vocale ?
Recherchez le symbole Écouter sur votre prochain livre pour voir si vous pouvez l’écouter. L’outil Écouter lit le texte Ă  haute voix pour vous, en surlignant le passage qui est en cours de lecture. Vous pouvez le mettre sur pause, l’accĂ©lĂ©rer ou le ralentir. DĂ©couvrez-en plus ici.
Est-ce que A History of Econometrics in France est un PDF/ePUB en ligne ?
Oui, vous pouvez accĂ©der Ă  A History of Econometrics in France par Philippe Le Gall en format PDF et/ou ePUB ainsi qu’à d’autres livres populaires dans Business et Business generale. Nous disposons de plus d’un million d’ouvrages Ă  dĂ©couvrir dans notre catalogue.

Informations

Éditeur
Routledge
Année
2007
ISBN
9781134352555
Édition
1

Part I.
Natural econometrics and the “system of the world”

De toutes les sciences naturelles, l’Astronomie est celle qui prĂ©sente la plus longue suite de dĂ©couvertes. Il y a extrĂȘmement loin, de la premiĂšre vue du ciel, Ă  la vue gĂ©nĂ©rale par laquelle on embrasse aujourd’hui, les Ă©tats passĂ©s et futurs du systĂȘme du monde. Pour y parvenir, il a fallu observer les astres, pendant un grand nombre de siĂšcles; reconnoĂźtre dans leurs apparences, les mouvemens rĂ©els de la terre; s’élever aux loix des mouvemens planĂ©taires, et de ces loix, au principe de la pesanteur universelle; redescendre enfin, de ce principe, Ă  l’explication complĂšte de tous les phĂ©nomĂšnes cĂ©lestes, jusque dans leurs moindres dĂ©tails. VoilĂ  ce que l’esprit humain a fait dans l’astronomie. L’exposition de ces dĂ©couvertes, et de la maniĂšre la plus simple dont elles ont pu naĂźtre les unes des autres, aura le double avantage d’offrir un grand ensemble de vĂ©ritĂ©s importantes, et la vraie mĂ©thode qu’il faut suivre dans la recherche des loix de la nature.
– Pierre-Simon Laplace, Exposition du SystĂȘme du Monde.
The next three chapters are explorations into an unfamiliar region of the history of economic ideas: the rise and the development of natural econometrics in France, from the 1830s to the 1860s. Despite differences, for instance relative to the way they use mathematics,1 Antoine Augustin Cournot, Jean-Edmond Briaune, and Jules Regnault share much at the methodological and the philosophical levels. All three drew inspiration from scientific programs of the period (mainly those defined by Laplace and QuĂ©telet), and analyzed economic issues with the help of statistics (data and instruments) and mathematics. Such a use of statistics and mathematics is closely dependent on their image of the economy and the society: both would be made up with causal, deterministic, divine and mathematical laws and structures (most often of a mechanical nature), and our three authors conceived statistics as a means to discover such laws and structures. In addition, these laws were understood as being parts of a general natural order, which would rule the social world as exactly as the natural world – the whole world was considered mathematically and mechanically organized and structured, and originating in a divine design. In that perspective, Cournot, Briaune, and Regnault aimed at discovering the secrets of the “system of the world” and at making Nature confess.
In the hands of these scholars, observation and statistical instruments play a central role. For Cournot, Briaune, and Regnault, science originates in observation. To my knowledge, none of them was directly involved in the collection of measures. But “from about 1830,” as Theodore Porter shows, “there occurred an enormous increase in the acquisition and use of quantitative information about nature, technology, and society alike” (Porter 2001:14). They could thus use data collected by administrations and institutions, for instance the Ministry of Agriculture or Paris Stock Exchange. Yet, for all three observed data were systematically associated with imperfection. Imperfection does not refer here to a bad quality of observed data, but rather to the functioning of the social world: although it is not chaos, this world would incorporate perturbation – for instance historical accidents or dissenting behaviors originating in ignorance – or, more radically, it is seen as having not reached yet its final and harmonious form. This explains that for these authors, statistical instruments had to be used in order to unveil the signs of constancy, order, and perfection in data. Here the statistical instrument par excellence is the average – these authors share much with QuĂ©telet in that perspective2 – from which accidents and imperfection could be eliminated. From averages, these scholars thought that timeless, invariant laws could be inferred and discovered: the “law of sales,” which relates price and quantity (Cournot); the “laws of proportionality,” which connect price to supplying (Briaune); and the “law of attraction” governing stock price behavior (Regnault). It is at this stage that statistics and mathematics become inseparable. From observation and from the use of statistical instruments, all three thought that it could be possible to identify mathematical laws ruling the society. In other words, for natural econometricians statistics plays an active role: it was considered a means to discover mathematical relationships and laws. Indeed, Cournot, Briaune, and Regnault believed that the social world – just like the natural world – would be a text written in mathematics, a text that it could be possible to decipher with the help of appropriate statistical instruments. In sum, we shall see in the next three chapters that for these three authors, the use of averages was seen as a means to unveil mathematical laws that would govern the society.
We can perceive here the way the methodology of natural econometricians and an idiosyncratic worldview are closely intertwined. These authors rooted their explorations of the economy in the belief that the social world would be, just like the natural world, ruled by a natural order. As we shall see in a more detailed way in the next chapters, the use of statistics and mathematics is here based on a particular image of the society. First, the society would be governed by a finite set of mathematical and mechanical3 laws. This idea legitimates two kinds of unity: an ontological unity – the whole “system of the world” would be made up with a set of laws that apply to society and nature – and a methodological unity – this worldview explains these authors’ search for economic translations of laws at work in the natural sciences. In other words, reductionism is here legitimated by the unity of phenomena supposed to prevail in the real world. Second, this ontological unity would find its roots in God’s design. In fine, natural econometricians saw statistics and mathematics as means for knowing laws they considered divine laws, and such laws were positively interpreted: they would work for harmony, at the individual and at the collective levels. For them, the social scientist would be an observer and a discoverer of God’s secret workshop, of a world they consider finite and harmonious. This explains a pivotal feature of natural econometrics: the task of the natural econometrician is to discover in observed data such a hidden order that, once identified, could lead societies to a stable and harmonious state, in full conformity with natural order and God’s design. Not surprisingly, for Cournot, Briaune, and Regnault, statistics and mathematics were means for identifying an “end of history,” the moment when no deviations from the natural laws occur and when historical time has no room anymore, when the economy becomes a timeless, ahistorical system.
The next three chapters are illustrations of this idiosyncratic interweaving of econometric ideas and a worldview dominated by the belief in a divine natural order. However, it is important to keep in mind that although econometric ideas emerged and took shape in the hands of Cournot, Briaune, and Regnault, this emergence never led to the constitution of a disciplinary field at the institutional level: natural econometrics remains a story of rather isolated figures. Basically, these authors can be considered innovators, in the sense that they largely break with the common practice and methodology of political economy of their time. Yet, they also perfectly fit into scientific paradigms of the ...

Table des matiĂšres