Muslim Civilization
eBook - ePub

Muslim Civilization

The Causes of Decline and the Need for Reform

M. Umer Chapra

  1. 224 pagine
  2. English
  3. ePUB (disponibile sull'app)
  4. Disponibile su iOS e Android
eBook - ePub

Muslim Civilization

The Causes of Decline and the Need for Reform

M. Umer Chapra

Dettagli del libro
Anteprima del libro
Indice dei contenuti
Citazioni

Informazioni sul libro

"[This is] a subject of such relevance and importance that one wonders why nobody else dealt with it in book form before."—Dr. Wilfried Hofmann

Muslim civilization has experienced a decline during the last five centuries after previously having undergone a long period of prosperity and comprehensive development. This raises a number of questions such as what factors enable Muslims to become successful during the earlier centuries of Islam and what led them to their present weak position. Is Islam responsible for this decline or are there some other factors which come into play? M. Umer Chapra provides an authoritative diagnosis and prescription to reverse this decline.

M. Umer Chaprais a research advisor at the Islamic Research and Training Institute of the Islamic Development Bank, Jeddah, and author of The Future of Economics and Islam and the Economic Challenge.

Show Additional Fields

Domande frequenti

Come faccio ad annullare l'abbonamento?
È semplicissimo: basta accedere alla sezione Account nelle Impostazioni e cliccare su "Annulla abbonamento". Dopo la cancellazione, l'abbonamento rimarrà attivo per il periodo rimanente già pagato. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui
È possibile scaricare libri? Se sì, come?
Al momento è possibile scaricare tramite l'app tutti i nostri libri ePub mobile-friendly. Anche la maggior parte dei nostri PDF è scaricabile e stiamo lavorando per rendere disponibile quanto prima il download di tutti gli altri file. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui
Che differenza c'è tra i piani?
Entrambi i piani ti danno accesso illimitato alla libreria e a tutte le funzionalità di Perlego. Le uniche differenze sono il prezzo e il periodo di abbonamento: con il piano annuale risparmierai circa il 30% rispetto a 12 rate con quello mensile.
Cos'è Perlego?
Perlego è un servizio di abbonamento a testi accademici, che ti permette di accedere a un'intera libreria online a un prezzo inferiore rispetto a quello che pagheresti per acquistare un singolo libro al mese. Con oltre 1 milione di testi suddivisi in più di 1.000 categorie, troverai sicuramente ciò che fa per te! Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui.
Perlego supporta la sintesi vocale?
Cerca l'icona Sintesi vocale nel prossimo libro che leggerai per verificare se è possibile riprodurre l'audio. Questo strumento permette di leggere il testo a voce alta, evidenziandolo man mano che la lettura procede. Puoi aumentare o diminuire la velocità della sintesi vocale, oppure sospendere la riproduzione. Per maggiori informazioni, clicca qui.
Muslim Civilization è disponibile online in formato PDF/ePub?
Sì, puoi accedere a Muslim Civilization di M. Umer Chapra in formato PDF e/o ePub, così come ad altri libri molto apprezzati nelle sezioni relative a Theologie & Religion e Islamische Theologie. Scopri oltre 1 milione di libri disponibili nel nostro catalogo.

Informazioni

Anno
2015
ISBN
9780860376064
1
IBN KHALDŪN’S THEORY OF DEVELOPMENT AND DECLINE1
Ibn Khaldūn’s entire model is condensed to a substantial extent, though not fully, in the following advice extended by him to the sovereign:
1. The strength of the sovereign (al-mulk) does not materialize except through the implementation of the Sharīʿah2…;
2. The Sharīʿah cannot be implemented except by the sovereign (al-mulk);
3. The sovereign cannot gain strength except through the people (al-rijāl);
4. The people cannot be sustained except by wealth (al-māl);
5. Wealth cannot be acquired except through development (al-ʿimārah);
6. Development can not be attained except through justice (al-ʿadl);
7. Justice is the criterion (al-mīzān) by which God will evaluate mankind, and
8. The sovereign is charged with the responsibility of actualizing justice (Muqaddimah (M): p. 39; Rosenthal’s translation (R): Volume 1, p. 80).3
The entire Muqaddimah is an elaboration upon this advice, which consists of, in Ibn Khaldūn’s own words: “eight wise principles (kalimāt ikamiyyah) of political wisdom, each one dovetailed with the other for mutual strength, in such a circular manner that the beginning or the end is indistinguishable” (M: p. 403; R: I, p. 82).
The strength of this model lies in its multidisciplinary and dynamic character. It is multidisciplinary because it links all important socio-economic and political variables, including the sovereign or political authority (G), beliefs and rules of behaviour or the Sharīʿah (S), people (N), wealth or stock of resources (W), development (g), and justice (j), in a circular and interdependent manner, each influencing the others and, in turn, being influenced by them.4
images
Since the operation of this cycle takes place through a chain reaction over a long period of three generations, or almost 120 years, circular causation as well as dynamism is introduced into the whole analysis. This helps explain how political moral, institutional, social, economic, demographic, and historical factors interact with each other over a long period of time to lead to the development and decline, or the rise and fall, of a state or civilization.
In a long term analysis of this kind, there is no ceteris paribus clause because none of the variables is assumed to remain constant. One of the variables acts as the trigger mechanism.5 If the other sectors of society react in the same direction as the trigger mechanism, the decay will gain momentum through an interrelated chain reaction such that it becomes difficult, over time, to identify the cause from the effect. If the other sectors do not react in the same direction, then the decay in one sector may not spread to the others and either the decaying sector may be reformed over time or the decline of the civilization may be much slower.
The role of the human being (N)
The centre of Ibn Khaldūn’s analysis is the human being6 because the rise and fall of civilizations is closely dependent on the well-being or misery of the people. This is, in turn, dependent not just on economic variables but also on the closely interrelated role of moral, institutional, psychological, political, social, and demographic factors through a process of circular causation extending over a long period of history (M: pp. 39 and 287; R: I, p. 80 and II, p. 105). This emphasis on the human being is in keeping with the Qur’ānic verses quoted in the Introduction, which state that, “God does not change the condition of a people until they change their own inner selves” (13:11), and that “Corruption has appeared everywhere because of what people have done” (30:41, italics added). These two verses along with many others emphasize the role of human beings themselves in their rise and fall. This is why all God’s Messengers (including Abraham, Moses, Jesus and Muammad) came to this world to reform human beings and the institutions that affect their behaviour.7
The role of development (g) and justice (j)
If human beings are the centre of analysis, then development and justice become the most crucial links in the chain of causation. Development is essential because unless there is a perceptible improvement in the well-being of the people, they will not be motivated to do their best (M: p. 287; R: II, p. 109). Moreover, in the absence of development, the inflow of scholars, artisans, labour and capital that need to take place from other societies to boost development further may not take place (M: pp. 362-3; R: II, pp. 271-6). This too may make it difficult to sustain development and may ultimately lead to a decline (M: p. 359; R: II, p. 270).
Development in Ibn Khaldūn’s model does not refer merely to economic growth (M: p. 39 and pp. 347-49; R: I, p. 39 and II, pp. 243-49). It encompasses all-round human development such that each variable enriches the others (G, S, N, W, j, and g) and is in turn enriched by them, contributing thereby to the true well-being or happiness of people and ensuring not only the survival but also the civilization’s rise. Economic development cannot be brought about by economic forces alone in isolation of the non-economic and spiritual forces of society. It needs moral, social, political and demographic support. If this support is not available, economic development may not be triggered, and if it is available, it may not, however, be sustainable.
Development is, however, not possible without justice. Justice, like development, though is also not conceived by him in a narrow economic sense but rather in the more comprehensive sense of justice in all spheres of human life. Ibn Khaldūn clearly states: “Do not think that injustice consists in only taking money or property from its owner without compensation or cause, even though this is what is commonly understood. Injustice is more comprehensive than this. Anyone who confiscates the property of someone else or who forces him to work for him, or presses an unjustifiable claim against him, or imposes on him a duty not required by the Sharīʿah, has committed an injustice. Collection of unjustified taxes is also injustice; transgression on another’s property or taking it away by force or theft constitutes injustice; denying other people their rights is also injustice” (M: p. 288; R: II, pp. 106-7). “One of the greatest injustices and the most destructive of development is the unjustifiable imposition of tasks on people and subjecting them to forced labour” (M: p. 289; R: II, pp. 108-9). Justice is considered so crucial by Ibn Khaldūn for development that he entitled a whole section as ‘Injustice Triggers the Destruction of Civilization’ (M: pp. 286-90; R: II, pp. 103-111). This is why justice and development are juxtaposed in the above diagram. “The extent to which property rights are infringed determines the extent to which the incentive to earn and acquire it goes…If the incentive is gone, they refrain from earning” (M: p. 286, R: II, p. 103). This adversely affects people’s efficiency, innovativeness, entrepreneurship, drive and other qualities, ultimately leading to society’s disintegration and decline.
Justice in this comprehensive sense leads to the development and strengthening of ʿaabiyyah, which has variously been translated as ‘social solidarity’, ‘group feeling’ or ‘social cohesion’. Justice promotes social solidarity by ensuring the fulfillment of mutual obligations and an equitable sharing of the fruits of development, and thereby, the well-being of all. This helps create mutual trust and cooperation, without which it is not possible to promote division of labour and specialization, which are necessary for the accelerated development of any economy (M: 41-43; R: I, 89-92). The absence of justice tends to generate discontent among people, dishearten them, and adversely affect their solidarity. This, in turn, not only adversely affects their motive to work but also saps their efficiency, entrepreneurial drive and other good qualities needed for development, ultimately leading to society’s disintegration and decline.
The crucial role that trust plays in development is now being rightly emphasized by economists8 and has become a part of ‘conventional wisdom’ or ‘embeddedness’. Ibn Khaldūn used the word ʿaabiyyah for what is, to a great extent, currently referred to as ‘social capital’ or ‘social infrastructure’.9 However, some scholars have raised objections against the use of the word ‘capital’ for something that is abstract and cannot be possessed, like the physical capital of individuals.10 Therefore, Ibn Khaldūn’s use of the expression ʿaabiyyah or ‘social solidarity’ seems to be a better alternative.
The role of institutions (S) and the government (G)
Justice, however, necessitates certain rules of behaviour called institutions in Institutional Economics and moral values in religious worldviews. They are the standards by which people interact with, and fulfill their obligations towards, each other (M: pp. 157-58; R: I, pp. 319-21). All societies have such rules based on their own worldview. The primary basis of these rules in a Muslim society is the Sharīʿah. “Divine Laws command the doing of good and prohibit the doing of what is evil and destructive” (M: p. 304; R: II, p. 142). They are, therefore, according to Ibn Khaldūn, “for the good of human beings and serve their interests” (M: p. 143; R: I, p. 292). Their Divine origin carries the potential to help promote their willing acceptance and compliance and to serve as a powerful cement for holding a large group together (M: pp. 151-52; R: I, pp. 305-8 and 319-22). This can help curb socially harmful behaviour, ensure justice, and enhance solidarity and mutual trust among people, thereby promoting development.
The Sharīʿah cannot, however, play a meaningful role unless it is implemented fairly and impartially (M: pp. 39 and 43; R: I, p. 80 and pp. 91-92). The Sharīʿah can only give rules of behaviour, it cannot itself enforce them. It is the responsibility of the political authority to ensure compliance through incentives and deterrents (M: pp. 127-28; R: I, pp. 262-63). The Prophet (pbuh) clearly recognized this by saying: “God restrains through the sultan (sovereign) more than what he restrains through the Qur’ān.”11 For Ibn Khaldūn, political authority has the same relationship to a civilization as form has to matter (M: pp. 371 and 376; R: II, pp. 291 and 300). “It is not possible to conceive of political authority without civilization and of civilization without political authority” (M: p. 376; R: II, p. 300). However, Ibn Khaldūn clearly emphasizes “good rulership is equivalent to gentleness” (M: p. 188; R: I, p. 383). “If the ruler is tyrannical and harsh in punishments… the people become fearful and depressed and seek to protect themselves by means of lies, ruses and deception. This becomes their characte...

Indice dei contenuti